It’s a natural and beneficial result of humans doing what humans have done since the beginning, making their families better off by working hard, inventing new stuff, keeping alert, looking around, making little deals, etc. The result of all this human liberty of choice has been globalization. At various scales of time, it’s been happening from the caves to the modern world, or from 1350 to 1800, or from 1776 to 2024.
Your neighborhood is a “single economy.” Most people in Manhattan don’t own cars, so the economic neighborhood in effect is smallish. A grocery store at the corner of Broadway and West 143rd Street can’t get away with charging $10 for a loaf of bread when another store two blocks away is charging $2. Within 10 blocks or so, the prices of the same brand of bread and the wages of the same quality dentist and the interest charged on a bank loan for the same credit rating will be pretty much the same.
On Long Island, everyone has a car, or two, or three, and the approximate sameness of prices extends for miles. And the overlap of neighborhoods means that anything that can move or can be offered easily to people who do move—bread, cars, dentists, bank loans (not so much for houses, which are usually immoveable by nature, and not so much across restricted borders, which are basically immovable by law)—is pretty much the same, as Woody Guthrie’s song “This Land Is Your Land” goes, from the redwood forest to the Gulf Stream waters. And the overlap of the overlaps, if not restricted by legal interventions by the state in the prices permitted, means that even globally, from the Amazon forest to the North Atlantic Current waters, the prices of wheat and iron and AK-47s are pretty much the same. Globalization.
The rough sameness of prices is not caused by a gracious state official enforcing a just price or by an evil monopolist imposing an unjust price. It’s caused by moderately alert customers making the sameness happen by exercising their liberty to shift from this to that purveyor of cars or dentistry or bread. No one will pay $10 for a loaf when she knows that a couple of blocks away she can pay $2. And the $2 grocery store will make sure she is alert to the difference. In Miami, which has a large population of retired people on fixed incomes, the prices of milk and toilet paper differ very little from store to store, within extraordinarily tight limits (a cent or two). The older people spend their days comparison shopping and sharply buying. Fool me once, shame on you; fool me twice, shame on me. If you thrill to economic jargon, you can call this “arbitrage.”
Globalization puts everyone whose government permits it into a global neighborhood in which the price of a Samsung TV at a Best Buy in Washington is pretty much the same as in Beijing or New Delhi. Big price differences in the same neighborhood would mean that you could easily do better. For example, as a low-price buyer, you could resell to a high-price buyer. Or as a low-price seller, you could advertise. Or as a high-price buyer, you could get smarter and look around for a better deal. The deals are voluntary and therefore must benefit both buyer and seller, a little or a lot. If permitted widely in a society, gross domestic product (GDP) per head goes up, a little or a lot. It happens by arbitrage, globalization, and common sense—the natural result of people liberated to better themselves while bettering others.
If the price of TVs is higher in Beijing, then suppliers will send TVs there, instead of to Washington. Ordinary prudence recommends “buy low, sell high” until the arbitrage of suppliers and demanders makes the price difference come down to a level at which no more deals are profitable. Economists call the result of such a mutual exhaustion of deals and the uniform prices that signal its achievement “Pareto efficiency.”
Arbitrage also applies, though often at a slower pace, to the labor, capital, materials, and especially to the technical know-how that goes into a Samsung TV. Again, it’s all about liberty. China opened economically after 1978, permitting exports and imports, permitting people to move to new jobs, and permitting people to start new businesses. In the largest migration in human history, hundreds of millions of Chinese from the interior moved one by one to the coast to work in the new factories at higher wages than at home. And the Communist Party let wages and prices be set by business suppliers and citizen demanders instead of by the state. Arbitrage ruled, and China waxed pretty prosperous.
Contrary to what you might have heard, however, there’s no “Chinese model” to be seen as an intriguing if authoritarian alternative to Western economic liberalism. The Communist Party of China would like you to believe there is. Nope. After 1978, the party merely started to permit an economic liberalism of the sort partially implemented in the West in the 19th century—though of course the party did not permit anything like a corresponding liberalism in politics. The “Chinese model” is merely “the capitalist road.”
The economic result of liberty in China’s economy? China’s income per head in 1978 was then lower than Sudan’s. It’s now about 12 times higher, about the same as Mexico’s (after adjusting for purchasing power parity), which is in turn about the global average. That’s still less than a third of U.S. income per head. But if Premier Xi Jinping fails in reverting to economic anti-liberalism with central planning and controls in prices, China’s on the way to parity in one to two generations. India likewise after 1991 opened to global prices, and as a result, if Premier Modi in India like Xi in China does not leave liberalism behind, India can expect parity with Europe and the United States in two or three long generations. Latin America and Africa cannot be far behind. Globalization, which is to say the force of arbitrage exercised by liberated people in the economy, spreads prosperity.