Trying to ensure that trade flows—or capital flows—are regularly “balanced” has no foundation in economic theory. Simply put, a country’s capital inflows do not have to match its capital outflows, just as a country’s trade inflows (imports) do not have to match its trade outflows (exports). The failure of these flows to “balance” does not prevent a nation from reaching its maximum economic potential. Economically, it would make as little sense to try to balance these figures as it would to try to balance the goods or capital flows between Walmart and American consumers.
The residents of any country can, for instance, finance their own expenditures entirely through domestic markets regardless of whether the country’s current account (or trade account) is in deficit or surplus with any other country. Even when consumers and businesses do rely on some external financing (directly or indirectly), their domestic spending on goods and services does not have to match these investment flows, just as Walmart can rely on external financing without “balancing” the amount investors contribute against what they spend in Walmart’s stores.
Put differently, the source of Walmart’s sales revenue is independent of its source of financing, just as Americans’ demand for imports is independent of how Americans finance their purchases. Nonetheless, some might argue that when foreign investors use dollars to buy, for example, American citizens’ shares of Apple and Exxon, they help to “finance” Americans’ purchases. Still, these types of share purchases do not have to balance against Americans’ goods purchases. It makes just as little sense to try to force such share purchases into balance as it would to try to force US pension funds’ stock purchases to balance Americans’ good purchases.
The flawed idea of balancing trade is a long-running misconception dating back to the days of Adam Smith (“Nothing, however, can be more absurd than this whole doctrine of the balance of trade”). The concept’s modern roots, which continue to bear rotten fruit even today, lie in a misunderstanding of the accounting framework used to create international (and national) economic accounts. These modern accounts can be traced to the 1920s, when the US Department of Commerce first published the balance of payments accounts, a system designed to measure the flow of goods and services abroad. Many aspects of these accounts have an arbitrary nature that if handled differently would result in a very different set of accounting outcomes.
For instance, all real estate transactions are classified as capital purchases (or sales), but there is no reason why these transactions could not be classified as consumption expenditures. Under the existing framework, if a Chinese resident buys a newly built house in the United States for $1 million, the transaction increases the US current account deficit. If, however, the same transaction was recorded as a consumption expenditure, it would decrease the current account deficit because it would be treated as an exported good (a US-produced good sold to a foreign resident). More broadly, if the overall accounting framework was designed, instead, to track the quantity of goods, a trade deficit would be referred to as a “goods surplus.” Regardless, a trade deficit does not indicate that anyone has lost anything or that anyone is owed anything.
Setting aside the arbitrary nature of these concepts and naming conventions, the core accounting framework remains the same for what has evolved into the present-day international economic accounts. These accounts are still designed to keep track of where all the money in the economy is going and where it is coming from. Thus, in theory, these accounts must balance because they account for all the different flows.
Still, this accounting requirement does not mean that US consumers must finance their spending from abroad to import more than they export. Similarly, the accounting requirement does not indicate that any amount of international financing must equal what any group of consumers spends on goods and services from abroad. Thus, on the surface, trying to make these amounts balance appears to be a misguided policy. In practice, this type of policy would be problematic because even the accounting balance that exists in the international accounts is not so easily achieved. Unsurprisingly, the empirical evidence does not support the notion that balancing trade flows is a worthy economic goal.