It is well known that access to goods and services that would not otherwise be available is a benefit of international trade. Even those who would restrict trade do not completely deny this. Their preferred trade restrictions are usually founded on other premises. However, the additional benefits of international trade are not as well known. Often overlooked, especially, is the reality that goods and services do not travel alone across international borders. They are frequently accompanied by new ways of thinking and new ways of transforming thoughts into new technologies, new products, and new ways of reworking and maintaining human civilization. Ideas are not static. Ideas are not motionless. Ideas travel. And ideas travel with trade.
Indeed, the spread of ideas is one of the foremost benefits derived from trade and from other aspects of economic globalization. A good is consumed. A service is used. Direct benefits are derived; but, as a result, fewer goods and services remain. The rivalry for goods and services “underlies the scarcity that is at the heart of most of economics,” as Stanford economist Chad Jones says in a VoxEU column about Paul Romer’s ideas. In contrast, ideas are nonrivalrous; as more people use an idea, there is no less of it to go around. As Jones has explained, once an idea exists, it is “technologically feasible for any number of people to use” it “simultaneously.” Ideas widen and expand. They do not disappear because they travel.
This is not an original thought. It is one for which Romer won the Nobel Prize in Economics in 2018. Romer demonstrated that the discovery of new ideas is at the heart of economic growth, because the application of new ideas is what inspires the innovations that increase productivity and therefore drive growth. As he demonstrated—starting with a seminal article published in 1990—the human capital of knowledge, which emerges and cumulates from new ideas, must be added to the traditional factors of economic production (i.e., land, labor, and capital).
As Jones summarized, simply replicating production requires a doubling of investment to produce doubled returns. An example would be a firm building an identical second factory and staffing it with identical machines and workers across the street from the firm’s first factory. In contrast, the dissemination of new ideas results in increasing returns on production because the same idea can be used repeatedly without any additional investment. An example would be the widespread use of a novel computer source code. These increasing returns from the employment of new ideas produce economic growth. This is one of numerous reasons why increased trade creates increased growth and, thus, why economic globalization does so as well.