As just noted, there were really two antitrust revolutions. The first involved advances in economists’ thinking about the effects of high and/or increasing concentration, the efficiency of business practices, the goals of antitrust, and the economic effects of regulation. We date this revolution as beginning in earnest in the 1950s and continuing to the present. The second had to do with the application of price theory and economic evidence to antitrust issues by federal agencies and the courts. We date this revolution as beginning about 1969 and continuing to the present. We use that year as a touchstone in telling our story.
Pre-1969: The use of price theory and its application to antitrust cases was a hallmark of what came to be called “the Chicago School” of thought, dating back to University of Chicago economist Aaron Director in the 1950s. As applied by Director and many of his students, as well as by academics at other institutions, especially Harvard, economic analysis often revealed that the logic employed by courts in evaluating antitrust cases was flawed, frequently confusing harm to competitors with harm to competition and consumers.
The basic antitrust doctrine pre-1969 can somewhat crudely be summarized as the belief that “big is bad” and that constraints imposed upon some firms by others likely reduce competition and harm consumers. As Ronald Coase wryly observed in his 1972 article “Industrial Organization: A Proposal for Research,” “One important result of this preoccupation with the monopoly problem is that if an economist finds something — a business practice of one sort or other — that he does not understand, he looks for a monopoly explanation. And as in this field we are very ignorant, the number of ununderstandable practices tends to be rather large, and the reliance on a monopoly explanation, frequent.” Furthermore, the standards applied by courts in interpreting the antitrust laws contained a confusing and often internally inconsistent amalgam of objectives.
Regarding horizontal mergers, the U.S. Supreme Court in Brown Shoe v. U.S. (1962) blocked a merger combining two firms that made and distributed shoes, ruling that though their combined market share would be small, a combined market share of as little as 5% sufficed to trigger antitrust liability. In U.S. v. Von’s Grocery (1966), the Court blocked a merger of two supermarket chains that would have had a combined market share of 7.5%. In U.S. v. Philadelphia National Bank (1963), the Court circumscribed efficiencies defenses and established a subsequently widely used presumption of harm from fairly modest post-merger concentration levels.
The Supreme Court’s decision in FTC v. Proctor and Gamble (1967) reflected the confused state of antitrust thinking at the time and went further than Philadelphia National Bank in dismissing efficiencies. P&G ruled that efficiencies generated by the proposed merger did not constitute a legally cognizable defense, stating, “Potential economies cannot be used as a defense to illegality, as Congress struck the balance in favor of protecting competition.” Indeed, the Court found that the transaction might make entry more difficult because an entrant would face a larger rival, and that was a reason to block the merger.
In 1968, the Department of Justice issued guidelines stating that horizontal mergers in unconcentrated markets would be challenged if each firm had 5% of the market. For vertical mergers, a firm with a 6% market share would not be allowed to purchase a supplying firm with a 10% share. By today’s standards, these shares are extremely low and would not raise anticompetitive concerns. Of course, if efficiencies cannot justify a merger, one might logically argue that virtually all mergers should be blocked.
For civil non-merger practices involving contractual restrictions, there was general hostility. Exclusive territories, resale price maintenance, tying, and other vertical practices were either treated as illegal per se or, at a minimum, assumed to be highly suspicious.
With respect to the involvement of professional economists at the federal competition agencies, it was not until 1973 that the DOJ formally established an internal group of economists to work on antitrust issues, and at the FTC the influence of economists was highly limited until the 1970s.
Post-1969: Beyond increased reliance on price theory, a major economic insight influencing antitrust came from Harold Demsetz in his 1973 article “Industry Structure, Market Rivalry, and Public Policy.” He made a simple but powerful point. The prevailing paradigm in studying markets was structure–conduct–performance, where improved performance (e.g., lower price) was assumed to be negatively correlated with market structure (e.g., concentration). Demsetz explained how that logic could easily be reversed. If efficient firms grew, concentration could increase and simultaneously prices could fall, quality could improve, and output could rise. Demsetz’s idea and other academic contributions offered empirical and theoretical support for his hypothesis, creating a revolution in thinking about when or whether concentrated markets are inherently objectionable.
Following the tradition of Coase’s 1937 article “The Nature of the Firm” and the use of price theory to understand business practices, Oliver Williamson’s 1975 book Markets and Hierarchies illustrated how efforts to minimize transactions costs across firms explained a lot of conduct that had previously been assumed to be anticompetitive. Transactions cost analysis could help explain, for example, why restrictions on distributors might be a desirable way to encourage distributors’ selling effort or manufacturers’ investments in marketing.
Another major development was the publication of Richard Posner’s 1976 book Antitrust Law: An Economic Perspective and Robert Bork’s 1978 book The Antitrust Paradox. One of the most significant achievements of both books, but especially identified with Bork’s, was that they helped transform antitrust into a policy focused solely on the concept of consumer welfare. (Bork used “consumer welfare” to mean total welfare, not simply the welfare of consumers. As discussed later, however, we think this distinction is minor from a practical viewpoint.) Bork’s clear advocacy for the proposition that consumer welfare — not protection of small businesses, not access by competitors to “essential” facilities created by others, not the guarantee of full employment or whatever other goal one could name — was (and should be) the goal of antitrust proved extremely influential. The consumer welfare standard came to be widely accepted and employed throughout the antitrust community and in the courts. That consensus has recently been questioned, an issue we discuss below.
In addition, Frank Easterbrook’s 1984 article “The Limits of Antitrust” framed antitrust policy in a way that continues to influence analysis greatly. Easterbrook explained that a decision maker must rely on inherently imperfect evidence when deciding whether to permit or condemn some behavior, and thus must consider the likely costs and benefits of at-times-incorrect decisions. These decisions, in turn, come to be influenced by the decision maker’s “priors.” We return to these ideas later when we discuss current criticisms of antitrust.
A final important development has to do with the efficiency properties of regulation as a substitute for the market. In his 1971 article “The Theory of Economic Regulation,” George Stigler explained that, in contrast to the widely held view that regulators are omniscient and act always in the public interest, regulators themselves have imperfect information, respond to financial and political incentives, and will often be swayed to act in the interests of — be “captured by” — the regulated. These factors have frequently resulted in the hoped-for cure being worse than the alleged disease.
Economic thinking and empirical knowledge have of course advanced since the 1970s, and those advancements have helped refine or replace some earlier ideas and policies. One cannot seriously argue that antitrust policy should be frozen in place and fail to adapt to new evidence and new learning. Below, we consider recent theoretical and empirical work claiming that the antitrust revolution has not been a success because it has failed to effectively constrain the growth of market power.
Changes in antitrust case law during the past half century have been remarkable. Many horizontal mergers that the Justice Department’s 1968 Guidelines would likely have challenged would not even appear on the radar screen today as potentially, let alone presumptively, harmful. There is now less emphasis on market shares and a greater emphasis on economic effects, and empirical evidence along with modern price theory are today important ingredients in just about every merger investigation — including ones involving highly concentrated markets.
Regarding vertical mergers, government enforcement efforts declined from pre-1969. Vertical mergers have been viewed as far less troubling than horizontal ones, both because there is no relevant market in which the number of suppliers is reduced and because of the efficiencies deemed likely to occur. Vertical Merger Guidelines issued by the Antitrust Division in 1984 were widely viewed as being highly permissive, though they have recently been replaced by ones containing more modern economic insights and reflecting a greater skepticism that vertical mergers are necessarily benign.
The 2010 Horizontal Merger Guidelines and 2020 Vertical Merger Guidelines both discuss the importance of efficiencies as part of the competitive impact analysis. Rarely (if ever) have courts, having found that a merger otherwise would be harmful to consumers, permitted the merger to go forward because of the claimed efficiencies. Efficiencies do, however, at times play a significant role in the agencies’ internal decision-making process. Despite the P&G case, government agencies and courts today evaluate carefully the parties’ claimed efficiencies, treating them — at least in principle — as a defense rather than an offense.
Since 1969, vertical and exclusionary practices once viewed as generally anticompetitive and treated as illegal per se — including resale price maintenance, exclusive territories, and exclusive dealing — are now considered untroubling in most circumstances and are evaluated under the rule of reason balancing test. Predation cases require a demonstration that the defendant has both priced below cost and can likely recoup its losses, raising significantly the bar to winning such cases.
As for the use of economists, both federal competition agencies have for decades employed dozens of full-time PhD economists, who are integrated into virtually all antitrust analyses.