This debate reduces to a factual question: do markets really tolerate thickets for any significant period of time so that innovation is actually delayed or hindered to a significant extent? In recent published research, I have tackled this question. The results are remarkably consistent across more than a century of experience in a variety of U.S. markets and survive close scrutiny of contemporary information and communications technology (ICT) markets characterized by intensive levels of patent acquisition and litigation. Contrary to the thicket argument, markets are adept at identifying, preempting, and unraveling intellectual property (IP) webs that could have slowed down innovation and commercialization. Whether it’s radio, aircraft, and automobiles in the 1900s and 1910s, petroleum refining in the 1920s and 1930s, or ICT from the 1990s through the present, patent-intensive markets do not appear to suffer from the increased prices, reduced output, and delayed innovation that should appear if the thicket thesis were correct. This is true if the number of IP holders is small, which might be expected since the costs of reaching agreement are relatively low; but it is also often true when the number of IP holders is large, which is not expected.
I started by looking closely at the ICT market. This would seem to be an especially fertile environment for a patent thicket. Hundreds to thousands of patents can cover various components of a single device and those patents are typically dispersed among multiple holders. In theory, it is plausible that holders would fail to cooperate, a thicket would arise, and such products as the iPhone would never see the light of day. Yet big-picture trends in ICT markets all point away from that dark scenario. Simply compare the price and functionality of a laptop, tablet, or any other personal computing device today with the closest equivalent device 10 years ago. The comparison is remarkable: functionality continues to improve significantly while, adjusted for quality, prices decline significantly. Despite being “burdened” by heavy patenting activities, the electronics market shows every symptom of a healthy innovation ecosystem: lots of new features, declining prices, and expanding output.
All of this suggests that the right question to ask is not, how are patents delaying innovation, but rather, how are innovation markets doing so well even though patents are being acquired and enforced intensively?
ICT MARKET
ICT markets have figured out two solutions to patent thickets: standard-setting organizations (SSOs) and patent pools. The SSO structure is well-known: firms cooperate to agree upon a technology standard and then commit to license “essential” patents relating to the standard on “reasonable and non-discriminatory” (RAND) terms. The problem, as is also well known, is that the meaning of what constitutes “essential” and RAND is sometimes unclear.
A next step taken in some market segments is the pooling mechanism. The patent pool in its current form is typically organized by a third-party administrator, which then makes the licensed patents available to all interested licensees subject to a known royalty schedule and other terms. The pool has two virtues. First, it achieves economies of scale in licensing patents held by multiple holders to an even larger group of licensees. Second, it eliminates the pricing uncertainty inherent to the SSO structure. In doing so, the pool can promote adoption of the underlying technology standard as compared to a market that operates through a series of multiple “one-off” licensing transactions. Pools currently in operation cover fundamental standards that drive the digital economy, such as the “codec” standards used to store, transmit, and display audio, visual, and other data through set-top boxes, DVD players and discs, Blu-Ray players and discs, digital televisions, digital cameras, and MP3 players. The seemingly mundane licensing mechanisms administered by patent pools supply a good part of the legal infrastructure behind the revolutionary communications devices that are now a part of everyday life.
The pooling phenomenon exemplifies the basic principle that markets don’t like to leave money on the table. For believers in the thicket thesis, transactional blockages are just that: a dead end. For the market, however, those blockages are a profit opportunity that invites entry by transactional entrepreneurs, who innovate by offering an administrative solution that makes all interested parties better off.
BEYOND ICT
A patent skeptic might still contend that the modern ICT market could be a special case. True enough, although this possibility stands in some doubt because repeated survey studies of potential patent thicket effects in the biomedical space—the setting in which the thicket thesis was initially asserted—have found little supporting evidence. Alternatively, it might be asked whether the ICT market has something to say about markets’ ability to address IP thickets in general.
In an inquiry relevant to both perspectives, I studied over a century’s worth of market efforts to resolve IP thickets through pooling and similar arrangements in technology and content markets. Based on publicly available information, I documented a total of 106 IP pools and similar arrangements during 1900–2015, which is almost certainly an understatement because of data limitations in older periods. My findings are set forth in Figure 1.
Clearly markets regularly form pools to address, preempt, and unravel patent thickets by pooling IP rights and have been doing so for a long time. The pattern persists from the beginning of the 20th century, when pools were formed to resolve thickets in automobiles, aircraft, and petroleum refining (among others), to the present, when pools have been formed to facilitate the promotion of various electronics standards. Markets even outperform theoretical models by successfully forming pools in high transaction-cost environments in which IP rights are held by a large group of dispersed holders. Of the 106 documented pools formed since 1900, I found that 22 were formed by groups consisting of 10 or more licensors. (These are all modern pools formed by third-party administrators.)
As Figure 1 shows, however, pooling largely ceased during the postwar period (approximately the 1940s through the mid-1990s). The reason is governmental distortion: while never making an explicit prohibition, the antitrust agencies had increased liability for pooling to such high levels that no firm would rationally undertake such a venture. From 1933 to 1938, I found that 21 documented pools were formed, of which 90% were contested on antitrust grounds and all of which were dissolved or modified. The lesson is clear: markets are adept at forming pools so long as courts and agencies honor the contractual arrangements that underpin them.