There is a strong consensus that people smoke less as the price increases, with a price elasticity of –0.4 for adults and –0.65 for adolescents.—Stanton Glantz
An extensive literature has shown that in response to a 1 percent increase in cigarette prices, overall cigarette consumption among adults would fall by somewhere between 0.3 and 0.7 percent, with about half of the reduction being attributed to the reduced number of current smokers and half attributed to the reduced number of cigarettes consumed per smoker.
—Hai-Yen Sung, Wendy Max, and James Lightwood, comment to U.S. Food and Drug Administration
The hypothesis expressed in these quotes, that higher cigarette taxes save a substantial number of lives and reduce health care costs by reducing smoking, is central to the argument in support of regulatory control of cigarettes through higher cigarette taxes.
Of course, lawmakers have other incentives for raising cigarette taxes. States collected more than $17 billion in cigarette excise taxes in 2012, representing slightly over 2 percent of all revenues collected at the state level. Still, government revenue ostensibly is a secondary consideration to policymakers.
What if, however, higher cigarette taxes do not have much effect on cigarette consumption? Would the public still support tax increases, particularly when the resulting revenue comes predominantly from low-educated, low-income persons? That question is not simply theoretical because there are plausible reasons to believe that, in the current high-tax environment, additional cigarette tax increases will have relatively little effect on smoking. Consider who currently smokes: at roughly $6 per pack (with approximately $2.50 of that tax) and after large increases in cigarette taxes over the last decade or so, those who smoke have revealed that they have strong preferences for smoking. Accordingly, it is reasonable to expect that further tax increases may have little effect on cigarette consumption.
Additionally, there is increasing concern over the regressivity of cigarette taxes. Compared to national smoking rates of 20.5 percent for men and 15.8 percent for women, more than a third of men and nearly a quarter of women with earnings below the federal poverty level were current smokers in 2012. Not only are people in poverty more likely to smoke, but they also devote a much larger share of their income to cigarette purchases. From 2010 to 2011, smokers earning less than $30,000 per year spent 14.2 percent of their household income on cigarettes, compared to 4.3 percent for smokers earning between $30,000 and $59,999 and 2 percent for smokers earning more than $60,000.
In this article, we summarize a study we conducted that focuses on the effect of recent, large cigarette tax increases on the smoking behavior of adults ages 18–74. Estimates from our study suggest that the association between cigarette taxes and either smoking participation or number of cigarettes smoked is small, negative, and not usually statistically significant. In terms of a price elasticity of demand, our estimates imply an elasticity of –0.065, which is one-fifth to one-tenth the size of the widely cited estimates offered by the CTCRE. Our substantially lower estimates of the responsiveness of cigarette consumption to changes in taxes (or prices) alter the basic cost and benefit calculation of cigarette taxes. For example, our estimates suggest that a $1 increase in federal cigarette taxes, as proposed by President Obama in his last budget, would reduce smoking by less than 1 percent. In sum, our study suggests that future cigarette tax increases will have relatively few public health benefits, and the justification of future taxes should be based on the public finance aspects of cigarette taxes such as the regressiveness, volatility, and rate of revenue growth associated with those taxes.
CIGARETTE TAXES AND CONSUMPTION
An often-referenced graph of the relationship between cigarette taxes (or prices) and consumption is almost sufficient to demonstrate the motivation for our study and the veracity of our findings. Figure 1 shows the relationship between cigarette consumption and cigarette taxes over the time period 1980–2009. One can see that, from 1980 to 1994, there was a relatively strong negative relationship between cigarette taxes and consumption—as taxes (and prices) increased steadily, consumption decreased steadily. However, after 1994, the relationship largely breaks down. Cigarette consumption continues on the same steady downward path after 1994, but taxes remain flat between 1994 and 1998 and then spike between 1998 and 2009, with no noticeable change in the trend in cigarette consumption. In short, after 1994 there is little association between changes in cigarette taxes and changes in consumption. Years with big tax (and price) increases are not associated with larger than average changes in consumption, and consumption continues to decline even when taxes (prices) remain largely unchanged.
At a minimum, Figure 1 strongly suggests that the responsiveness of cigarette consumption to price has declined markedly in the recent period. Remarkably, this and similar figures are still used by advocates to argue for the public health benefits of cigarette taxes. For instance, according to the anti-smoking group Campaign for Tobacco-Free Kids, "Although there are many other factors involved, comparing the trends in cigarette prices and overall U.S. cigarette consumption from 1970 to 2007 shows that there is a strong correlation between increasing prices and decreasing consumption." That assertion may have been true prior to 1994, but over the last 20 years it is no longer supported by the data. Instead, the data in Figure 1 appear to be consistent with our findings—that, at most, in the recent past, there was a small negative association between cigarette taxes and smoking. We now summarize a more sophisticated assessment of this issue.
OUR APPROACH
To conduct our analysis, we focused on states with recent large cigarette tax increases. Specifically, we selected 19 states enacting 22 of the largest tax increases during the period covered by our data. The decision to focus on large tax increases is motivated by the simple argument that changes in consumption should be greatest for the largest tax increases. Focusing on large tax increases is also advantageous from an empirical standpoint because larger effects are easier to detect reliably than smaller effects.
For each state in our sample, we selected a group of comparison states that are matched on smoking rates and other demographic factors in the period prior to the state tax increase. States with statistically similar rates of smoking in the pre-tax period and that had no corresponding change in their cigarette tax were paired with the treatment state enacting the tax increase. As an example, Oklahoma's state cigarette excise tax was raised from $0.23 to $1.03 on January 1, 2005. Six states (Kentucky, Missouri, Indiana, Kansas, Tennessee, and West Virginia) had rates of smoking statistically similar to Oklahoma's in the pre-tax period; however, Kentucky also enacted a cigarette tax increase and therefore was excluded from the group of comparison states. This process was repeated for all 22 instances of tax increases we examined, resulting in an average of 11.7 states qualifying as comparison states for each "large tax increase" treatment state.
Using the sample of 22 treatment states that experienced large tax increases and their corresponding comparison group of states, we conducted a pre- and post-test comparison; we compared changes in smoking pre-to-post tax increase in the state that had raised taxes to the change in smoking over the same period in the comparison group of states that did not raise taxes. We combined these 22 "experiments" into one group to obtain the average (weighted) change in smoking caused by taxes in the 22 states.
To test the validity of our approach, we created a placebo experiment in which we chose the same treatment/control groupings, but in periods when there were no tax changes for either the treatment state or comparison states. We then randomly assigned a $0.50 tax increase to one of the states in the group and conducted our analysis as described above. Essentially, we created a series of "pseudo" tax increases using states and time periods where no actual tax changes occurred. If our approach was valid, then we expected estimates from the placebo experiment to be zero because no actual tax increase took place. In fact, the validity of our approach based on this placebo analysis was strongly confirmed.
The data for our analysis were drawn from 15 waves of the Current Population Survey Tobacco Use Supplement (CPS-TUS), which is a survey of tobacco use sponsored by the National Cancer Institute spanning the years 1995–2007. The CPS-TUS asks several questions regarding tobacco usage, including whether the respondent was an everyday or someday smoker. In addition, if the respondent is classified as an everyday smoker, the survey asks for the average number of cigarettes smoked each day. We defined smokers to be everyday smokers and consider someday smokers to be nonsmokers in order to maintain consistency in our estimates of smoking intensity.
We constructed two dependent variables. The first is a measure of smoking propensity and is a binary variable equal to 1 if the respondent is an everyday smoker and 0 otherwise. The second dependent variable is a measure of smoking intensity and is equal to the average number of cigarettes smoked daily. (This variable equals 0 if the respondent is a nonsmoker.)
The CPS-TUS also contains demographic information including age, sex, race, education, marital status, employment status, and family income, which are used in the analyses. We limit the sample to adults ages 18–74.