The Court also surprised observers by ruling 7–2 that the ACA unconstitutionally coerces the states by threatening to deny all federal Medicaid funding—not just expansion funding—to states that do not expand their Medicaid rolls as the statute prescribes. While prior Supreme Court precedents had recognized the theoretical possibility that Spending Clause legislation could unconstitutionally commandeer recipient states, no spending legislation had actually been struck down on coercion grounds. Few observers expected the state challengers to succeed on their coercion argument, particularly by a 7–2 vote.
Now that the dust has settled somewhat, we may assess the likely consequences of the decision in National Federation of Independent Business v. Sebelius. This article briefly summarizes the reasoning underlying the decision’s individual mandate ruling. It then considers what lies ahead for health insurance and medical care in the United States if the ACA, as modified by NFIB, is not repealed. Be warned: the picture isn’t pretty.
The Roberts Court’s Decision
As both Justice Roberts’ opinion for the Court and the joint dissent of Justices Antonin Scalia, Anthony Kennedy, Clarence Thomas, and Samuel Alito emphasized, our federal government is one of limited powers. The Bill of Rights precludes the government from imposing rules and taking actions that violate certain fundamental rights like the freedoms of speech, association, and religion. In addition, Article I of the Constitution limits congressional power by exhaustively cataloging the things Congress is authorized to do; congressional action that is not authorized is forbidden. Accordingly, for an act of Congress to pass constitutional muster, it must be both authorized by the empowering provisions of Article I and not forbidden by the constraints in the Bill of Rights.
The primary issue in NFIB was whether the so-called individual mandate—the provision of the ACA requiring most individuals to purchase health insurance or pay a penalty to the government—was authorized by Article I. The government contended that the mandate was authorized by Congress’s express power under the article’s Section 8, Clause 3 to “regulate Commerce … among the several States.” The state challengers, by contrast, maintained that individuals who had elected not to purchase health insurance had not thereby engaged in commerce, so forcing them to do something commercial—to enter commerce—was not itself a regulation of commerce. Five members of the Court (Chief Justice Roberts and Justices Scalia, Kennedy, Thomas, and Alito) agreed and held that the Commerce Clause does not authorize Congress to order individuals to purchase insurance from a private company. They further agreed that the mandate was not authorized by the Article I provision empowering Congress to “make all Laws which shall be necessary and proper” for carrying out its Commerce Clause authority. The mandate was not “proper,” the five justices concluded, because it would compel—not regulate—commerce, and any power conferred by the Necessary and Proper Clause must be incidental to, not greater than, the expressly enumerated powers.
But all this was not enough to undermine the individual mandate’s constitutionality. Having concluded that the mandate is not a valid exercise of Congress’s authority under the Commerce and Necessary and Proper Clauses, Justice Roberts invoked a longstanding interpretive canon that calls for the Court, if possible, to interpret statutes in a way that preserves their constitutionality. Because he had determined that the mandate could not be upheld on the aforementioned grounds, Justice Roberts was willing to adopt what he characterized as a “fairly possible,” though not the “most straightforward,” reading of the ACA—namely, that the statute does not make it illegal not to buy health insurance, but instead merely imposes a tax, labeled a “penalty,” on the failure to do so. Congress’s calling the payment a penalty rather than a tax, Justice Roberts reasoned, was enough to preclude application of the Anti-Injunction Act, which limits courts’ jurisdiction to hear challenges to tax laws but, as a mere statute, may be overridden by congressional action. But, according to the Chief Justice and Justices Ruth Bader Ginsburg, Stephen Breyer, Sonia Sotomayor, and Elena Kagan, congressional labeling alone is not enough to keep a penalty from amounting to a tax for constitutional purposes. The penalty for not buying insurance is constitutionally a tax, the majority reasoned, because it is relatively small in size, has no “scienter” requirement (i.e., does not require an intentional failure to purchase insurance), and is to be collected by the Internal Revenue Service. Accordingly, the penalty for failure to purchase insurance is constitutionally authorized as long as it meets the Constitution’s restrictions on Congress’s taxing power. The majority concluded that it does.
Constitutional law scholars will spend years dissecting the reasoning and exploring the broad implications of NFIB’s individual mandate ruling, and an exhaustive constitutional analysis of the decision is beyond the purview of this article. Instead, the remainder of this article focuses on the narrower and more immediate issue of how the modified ACA will alter health insurance and medical care in the United States.
Implications
In June 2009, at the outset of the health care reform debate, President Obama’s Council of Economic Advisers identified “two key components of successful health care reform: (1) a genuine containment of the growth rate of health care costs, and (2) the expansion of insurance coverage.” When the ACA was finally enacted, it became apparent that proponents had deemphasized the former component and focused almost exclusively on the latter. As interpreted and modified by the NFIB Court, however, the ACA is likely to provide neither. Instead, we can expect health insurance premiums to rise, the underlying cost of medical care—the primary driver of insurance premiums—to continue to grow at pre-ACA (or perhaps higher) rates, and insurance coverage to expand less than ACA proponents predicted.
Health insurance premiums | As the government repeatedly stressed in the NFIB argument, the individual mandate was necessary because of two constraints the ACA places on insurance companies. The first, “guaranteed issue,” precludes insurance companies from denying or dropping coverage because of preexisting conditions. The second, “community rating,” requires insurers to set premiums solely on the basis of age, smoker status, and geographic area, without charging higher premiums to sick people or those susceptible to sickness. Taken together, these two constraints on insurance pricing create a perverse incentive for young, healthy people to refrain from purchasing health insurance until they need medical care. After all, they can always obtain coverage immediately upon becoming ill or injured (thanks to guaranteed issue), and (thanks to community rating) the insurer is forbidden to charge them a higher price reflective of the virtual certainty that they will make large claims. The penalty-backed individual mandate was designed to prevent young, healthy people from dropping or declining to purchase insurance, thereby leaving only the older and infirm in the covered population.
If young, healthy people do exit the pool of premium-paying insureds, insurance premiums will skyrocket. That is because health insurance premiums are based on the likely health care expenditures of the covered population. The greater the percentage of young and healthy (low expenditure) individuals in the group, the lower the resulting premiums. Conversely, when the young and healthy drop out so that the pool of insureds is, on average, older and more infirm, premiums will rise. And, of course, the higher insurance premiums rise, the more sensible it becomes for the relatively healthy to drop their insurance, pay the small “tax,” and wait to get sick before signing up for increasingly costly coverage. Efficacious penalties for failure to purchase insurance, then, are required to prevent “adverse selection” and ensure that insurance policies, as regulated by the ACA, remain affordable.
But penalties do not deter if they are set too low. Say, for example, that a parking meter costs a dollar, but the penalty for not feeding the meter is only a quarter. Who would feed the meter? Unless the expected penalty for an expired meter (the fine times the likelihood of detection) exceeds a dollar, feeding the meter is irrational.
The ACA creates a similar situation because the statutory penalty for not carrying health insurance is quite low, much lower than the cost of insurance. As Justice Roberts observed:
[I]ndividuals making $35,000 a year are expected to owe the IRS about $60 for any month in which they do not have health insurance. Someone with an annual income of $100,000 a year would likely owe about $200. The price of a qualifying insurance policy is projected to be around $400 per month.
It makes little sense for a young, healthy person in this situation to pay $400 a month for health insurance when she can instead opt to pay a penalty of $60 a month until she needs health care, at which point she can contact a health insurer and be assured of coverage (because of guaranteed issue) at rates not reflecting her impaired health (because of community rating).
Now, this analysis does not account for subsidies the ACA provides to purchase health insurance. Families earning up to four times the federal poverty level (FPL) may qualify for a subsidy on health insurance purchased on a state exchange that complies with the ACA. But there are two reasons to believe that, even with these subsidies, many young and healthy people will refrain from purchasing health insurance. First, the subsidies are too small. For subsidy-eligible families of four (those earning up to 400 percent of FPL), the annual penalty for failure to purchase insurance will never exceed $2,085 (adjusted for inflation from 2016 dollars). Out-of-pocket costs for subsidized insurance, by contrast, will be significantly more than that amount for all but the poorest families. Table 1 catalogs, for different family income levels, the maximum income percentage and out-of-pocket dollars the family will have to pay for subsidized insurance in 2016, the percentage difference in outlays for the family’s two options (buy insurance or pay the penalty), and the family’s likely decision.
As the table reveals, at all but the lowest income levels it makes more sense for healthy families to refrain from purchasing insurance and pay the penalty until insurance coverage is needed. In fact, until 2016, even families with the lowest two income levels on the table would be better off foregoing insurance purchases. Because the no-insurance penalties are phased in between 2014 and 2016 (they are only $285 in 2014 and $975 in 2015), they are initially less than the out-of-pocket cost of a qualifying insurance policy. It is likely, then, that even low-income healthy families will drop out of the insurance pool in 2014 and 2015, driving up insurance premiums for those remaining in the pool.
In addition to being too small, the subsidies for purchasing insurance may not be available in many states. The text of the ACA provides for the subsidies only on purchases made through exchanges that the states voluntarily establish. While proponents of the ACA presumably assumed that all states would establish such exchanges so as to make subsidies available to their citizens, a great many states (36 as of the time this article was drafted) either have declared an intention not to set up a state exchange or have made little movement in the direction of doing so. The IRS has taken the position that the subsidies should also be available through federal exchanges set up as a “fallback” in states that do not establish their own. It insists that expanding the subsidies is consistent with the purpose of the statute. That is not altogether clear, for legislative history suggests that Congress deliberately provided subsidies only through state-established exchanges in order to encourage states to set up and manage such exchanges. In any event, the statutory language limiting subsidies to state exchanges is quite clear and courts are generally loathe to exalt a statute’s purported purpose over its clear text, particularly when congressional intent is ambiguous.
In the end, then, the ACA sets penalties that are too low to induce young and healthy people to purchase insurance, even when their purchases are subsidized as the statute provides. Proponents of the ACA, who certainly understood the perverse incentives created by mandating guaranteed issue and community rating, must have recognized that the penalties were too low to prevent widespread adverse selection. They likely assumed, though, that the deficient penalties for failure to carry insurance were a “bug” that Congress would eventually fix once the act was put in place and became operative. During debate over the ACA, proponents needed for the penalties to be low so that they could maneuver the statute through the political process; they figured they could fix the deficiencies later.