In the near future, one critical, emerging pricing issue will be how rapid is the uptake of a blockbuster class of drugs called “biosimilars.” These can be thought of as generic versions of biologics, drugs that are complex biological molecules derived from living cells. Typical biologics include vaccines, allergenic products, gene therapy, and many cancer and arthritis drugs. (See “Still Awaiting the ‘Biosimilars’ Revolution,” Spring 2015.)
Generic medicines are a critical element of Americans’ health care. Since 1984, the marketing of generic versions of chemically synthesized “small-molecule” drugs—such as those used commonly to control diabetes, blood pressure, cholesterol, and pain—has been governed by legislation commonly known as the Hatch–Waxman Act. That law allows the approval of generics through an abbreviated and less costly pathway than for innovator—or brand-name—drugs, not requiring new clinical trials but only a demonstration of “bioequivalence.” That balances the need to preserve the industry’s incentive to innovate, supported by the patent system, with the benefits of competition.
The result has been a robust and hugely important generic drug industry. More than four of every five drug prescriptions are for generic drugs, which saves consumers over $200 billion annually. The price effect of newly available generic drugs is often rapid and impressive: when the first generic copy of a typical small-molecule drug reaches pharmacies, there is about a 30% drop in price, often reaching 80% as additional generic versions appear. Thus, brand-name drugs like Lipitor and Prilosec, which were economic blockbusters while their patents were intact and they had the market to themselves, have seen their market-share and revenues plummet once generics became available.
Disappointing results / When the pathway for generic drugs was established 30 years ago, biologics as a class were inconsequential compared to simpler small-molecule drugs. Today, biologics are common. Each year since 2010, they have represented the majority of new drugs that come onto the market, and they account for more than 20% of U.S. drug expenditures, with global sales topping $150 billion annually. Last year, eight of the top 10 drugs by worldwide sales were biologics.
Hoping to replicate for biologics the success of Hatch-Waxman, in 2009 Congress passed the Biologics Price Competition and Innovation Act (BPCIA), which was supposed to begin the process of creating a generic–like pathway for biosimilars. Passage of the BPCIA was accompanied by glowing predictions of cost savings. The Congressional Budget Office estimated that biosimilars would reduce total drug expenditures by $25 billion over 10 years. Steve Miller, chief medical officer of the prescription benefit plan provider Express Scripts, was far more bullish, estimating that cost savings could be a whopping $250 billion by 2024. So far, however, those high expectations have failed to materialize.
Looking primarily through a regulatory lens, I predicted four years ago that these predictions were far too optimistic. I had several reasons for this skepticism.
First, biologics are generally made in living cells, usually bacteria, yeast, or cultured mammalian cells that have been reprogrammed to synthesize the drug by means of the insertion of new genetic material. The choice of cells and purification methods determines the nature and amount of contaminants in the final formulation. Nothing is ever 100% pure, but it’s much easier to get closer to that goal with small molecules. For generic versions of small molecules, the manufacturer must only demonstrate bioequivalence, the absence of significant differences from the innovator drug in its availability at the site of its action (for example, in the blood or gastrointestinal tract). However, for biologics, various kinds of enzymatic modifications and impurities inevitably introduce variation, sometimes with unexpected results. Experience has shown that even minuscule differences in the substances that accompany—or contaminate—the active drug substance can be clinically significant, which makes the creation of “generic” versions difficult. This is not just a biological concern, but a political one.
Second, because of these differences, regulators view biosimilars somewhat warily. The U.S. Food and Drug Administration announced in 2012 “an abbreviated pathway that will depend on existing data” for biosimilars if “there are no clinically meaningful differences” from the original product. That requirement may sound innocuous, but it’s a high bar to clear. It has ensured that in spite of many predictions to the contrary, this new biosimilar pathway has neither significantly changed the drug development landscape nor put a significant dent in escalating medical costs.
Even miniscule differences in the substances that accompany—or contaminate—the active drug substance can be clinically significant.
Understanding this failure requires some history. The FDA’s involvement with biosimilars is not new. Even before the 2012 policy was announced, regulators had approved a small number of “follow-on biologics”—biosimilars by another name. Scientific considerations dictated that all of them required a substantial amount of laboratory and clinical testing—a far more elaborate, expensive process than has been required for small-molecule generics. Despite the 2012 announcement, the FDA’s approach to such products has not eased, and this is reflected in the approval numbers. The first U.S. biosimilar was approved by the FDA in 2015 and only 18 have been approved to date. This compares with 58 by the European Medicines Agency.
Why the discrepancy? The FDA’s experience with biologics, both new and follow-on varieties, is revealing. A vivid example of the potential problems with biologics occurred between 2001 and 2003, when two versions of a biologic called epoetin alfa, which treats anemia, were sufficiently different that one of them actually caused a 30-fold greater frequency of a severe kind of anemia. The drugs were supposed to be the same but the clinical outcomes were very different.
Cognizant of such phenomena, the FDA has long considered that even minor changes in the production of biological drugs—including the same isolation and purification procedures applied at significantly larger scale than previously—yield a distinct new drug that must undergo an independent demonstration of safety and efficacy. For example, some years ago the FDA reviewed a request to manufacture a biologic used to treat Pompe disease—a debilitating inherited disorder—in a new, larger-scale manufacturing facility. Although the drug was produced by the same company with the same process as at smaller scale, the FDA considered the larger-scale version to be a new product and even required that it adopt a different name; the two products were marketed as Myozyme and Lumizyme.
The head of the FDA’s drug center, Janet Woodcock, has acknowledged in congressional testimony the scientific and technical challenges posed by biosimilars. She emphasized the importance of possible immunogenicity—the stimulation of an immune response (which can both inactivate the drug and cause serious side effects)—by a biosimilar drug. She noted that “the ability to predict immunogenicity of a protein product, particularly the more complex proteins, is extremely limited,” and concluded that “some degree of clinical assessment of a new product’s immunogenic potential will ordinarily be needed.” The bottom line is that clinical trials—which may need to be large in order to achieve sufficient statistical power—are generally required to demonstrate the efficacy and especially the safety of biosimilars before the FDA approves them.
A third problem for biosimilars is that various non-regulatory economic factors create disincentives to the uptake of biosimilars once they are approved. Pacific Research Institute economist Wayne Winegarden explains two of these disincentives:
One of the more important obstructions is the current “buy-and-bill” reimbursement system that dis-incents lower-cost biosimilars. Under this system, providers purchase medicines and then, once the medicines have been administered to the patients, bill insurers for the costs of the medicine plus their mark-up. The provider mark-up is typically a percentage of the medicine’s price. Since a biosimilar’s price is less than a biologic’s price, providers lose money when they prescribe a lower-priced biosimilar medicine instead of a higher-priced biologic medicine. These losses are not de minimis either. A 2017 study found that in the case of one medicine class, infliximab, broad adoption of the biosimilars could decrease providers’ profits by as much as $100 million.
Next, insurance plans commonly include fail-first policies. Typically, the purpose of fail-first policies is to require patients to use lower-priced generic medicines first, then, only if the generic medicines fail to sufficiently help the patients, can a more expensive branded medicine be prescribed. As applied to biosimilars, however, fail-first policies work in reverse. In this case, the insurance clauses will only allow patients to use the less expensive biosimilars if they first failed on the more expensive biologics. Thus, as currently applied, fail-first policies bias the market against less expensive biosimilars, harming competition in the process.
Even after biosimilars are approved, their adoption rates have not been as high as predicted. Only time will tell whether they will moderate drug prices.
A fourth problem is that patents have protected market share and the pricing power of the brand-name biologics. Most of these drugs haven’t been on the market long enough for their patents to expire, at which time competitors would be permitted to launch cheaper biosimilars. It should be noted, though, that many of the initial wave of biologics are beginning to reach the end of their exclusivity period.
One final problem is that the uptake of biosimilars has been slowed by several strategies devised by the manufacturers of the brand-name biologics in order to maintain market share. For example, originators have inhibited the sales of biosimilars by gaming the rebate system. The originators offer rebates to health insurers that agree to contracts that exclude biosimilars or, at least, provide the brand-name biologic with preferential placement on their drug formularies, which dictate how much patients pay at pharmacies. Why would insurers enter into such arrangements? Possibly because biosimilars are viewed skeptically as a result of a kind of whispering campaign to disparage them.
Although the BPCIA states explicitly that a biosimilar must be highly similar to, have the same mechanism of action as, and have no clinically meaningful differences from the reference product, that has not deterred some makers of the more expensive brand-name products from raising theoretical concerns about the safety and efficacy of biosimilars. They claim that their goal is solely to inform and protect patients, but as H.L. Mencken said, “When someone says, ‘It’s not about money,’ it’s about money.”
Conclusion / The result of all these factors is that even after the biosimilars are approved, their adoption rates are not as high as predicted. That is costly to patients and insurers. According to a study by the RAND Corporation, biosimilars are projected to be priced 10–51% below the corresponding brand-name biologic. That has not borne out.
Winegarden estimates that small-molecule generic drugs “saved the U.S. health system $1.67 trillion between 2007 and 2016 alone.” His analysis indicates that with increasing market share of currently approved biosimilars, the savings could run well into the billions. However, at least in the short-term, the obstacles are imposing. Only time will tell whether biosimilars will become a major factor in moderating drug costs, as they should.