The Rail Industry Has Thrived Since Deregulation
The Staggers Act, which became law in 1980, essentially ended the practice of government setting prices for transactions between shippers and railroads. That allowed railroads to begin investing in their networks with the expectation of earning a reasonable return. It ended an era of bankruptcy and disinvestment that had plagued the industry since the advent of cross-country trucking and the Interstate Highway System.
The law quickly reversed the degradation of the nation’s rail infrastructure. In the ensuing decades, the railroads dramatically increased their investments in tracks, cars, and network infrastructure. Today, the United States has the most productive and efficient freight rail networks in the world.
After the Staggers Act, the cost of shipping goods by rail fell steadily. By moving more traffic over a modernized network, railroads could offer lower prices and increase profits at the same time. At the time the act passed, the freight rate per ton mile averaged 2.87¢, but by 1985 it began to fall steadily. Twenty years later, it was less than half of its 1980 rates after adjusting for inflation.
Lower prices and increased capacity allowed rail to steal freight business from the trucking industry, which the government also deregulated in 1980 with the Motor Carrier Act. At the time of deregulation, goods could be shipped by rail for almost half the cost of going by truck. Today, shipping goods by rail costs about 20% of shipping by truck. See Figure 1.
Railroad Switching Economics
Railroads do often voluntarily provide their competitors with access to their tracks and customers. This can take many forms, from the incumbent picking up cars from an origin and delivering them to a competitor’s interchange or picking up cars from an interchange and delivering them to a terminus, to simply allowing a competitor to use the incumbent’s tracks, either as a pass-through or permitting the competitor to service shippers on those tracks.
These “interline” service arrangements are made with railroads’ eyes on their finances. Railroads have very high fixed costs — railbeds and tracks are expensive to lay and maintain — and those costs must be covered despite considerable variation in shippers’ demand. Given that environment, railroads tend to use differential pricing: shippers that are more inclined to switch to alternative transport modes will be charged a price closer to the railroads’ marginal cost, while shippers with limited alternatives — think of goods that are especially difficult or dangerous to move by truck — pay higher prices. The latter shippers still benefit from transacting with the railroads, but they would prefer to pay the lower prices charged to others. Some of these shippers — including large chemical companies — want the government to step in and reduce their shipping costs in some way.
Reviving Mandatory Reciprocal Switching
The Staggers Act gave the Interstate Commerce Commission (now the STB), the power to regulate and maintain a competitive balance in the industry. In 2011, a coalition of shippers called the National Industrial Transportation League petitioned the STB to broaden a more modest switching rule that was then (and still is) on the books. Those efforts culminated in 2016 with the STB proposing a rule for mandatory reciprocal switching across the seven Class I railroads, which are railroads with annual operating revenues of $250 million or more. The railroads vigorously opposed the idea and the STB never finalized it.
In July 2021, President Biden issued Executive Order 14036 targeting corporate consolidation and other practices the administration deemed to be wrongful exercises of market power. Included in the order is a provision directing the STB to “further competition in the rail industry and to provide accessible remedies for shippers.” The order asked the STB to consider reducing the burden of proof for requiring railroads to allow other railroads to compete with them on their lines. This has revived the idea of mandatory reciprocal switching.
To understand what this would entail, suppose that Acme Chemical Company has one set of tracks that leads to its facility, and the tracks are solely owned and operated by Railroad A. Acme’s customer is in Chicago, 800 miles away. Railroad A can deliver the load directly to the customer on its tracks, but Acme would like a competitive quote from a competing railroad, B. Railroad B’s network connects with the Chicago customer as well, and 25 miles away from Acme’s facility the networks for Railroad A and B connect. Acme wants to get a quote from B that would force A to do the laborious pick-up and drop-off at the connector between A and B, where Acme’s goods would then be transported by Railroad B the final 775 miles to the receiver.
At present, the STB can mandate a reciprocal switch only in the case of illegal and anticompetitive behavior, conditions that shippers claim are difficult to prove. The 2016 proposal would have compelled a railroad to perform a switch if four conditions were met:
- The shipper’s or receiver’s facilities for which switching is sought are served by only one Class I rail carrier.
- There is no effective inter- or intramodal competition for the rail shipments.
- There is, or can be, a “working interchange” between the incumbent carrier and another Class I within a “reasonable distance” of the shipper’s facilities.
- The arrangement is feasible and safe, and it would not unduly hamper the ability of either carrier to serve its shippers.
Notice that the proposed rule does not require that a nearby interchange already exist between the two railroads, only that there “can be” one. In effect, the language suggests that a shipper’s successful petition could serve to force a railroad to construct such an interchange — a not-insignificant capital expenditure — for the benefit of its competitors.
In essence, the proposed rule would give shippers a unilateral right to request a railroad do something that would both reduce its productivity and its revenue if it can be asserted to be “feasible and reasonable.” There would be no consideration of the costs it would impose on the railroad.
The Drawbacks of Forced Reciprocal Switching
One way for the STB to satisfy EO 14036 would be to resurrect and enact the 2016 proposed rule, and some observers believe that will be attempted. But mandating reciprocal switching in a multitude of situations would create many problems in the rail freight industry.
Worse service / Reciprocal switching entails costly and time-consuming operations for the railroad. This can be analogized to an airline passenger who can only reach his destination through a connecting flight between two different airlines. Rather than simple, low-risk, and fast, the traveler has a complex route at greater risk of disruption. In the case of rail freight, the incumbent railroad — and its other shippers — would bear much of that cost.
And reciprocal switching is more complicated than navigating connecting flights. While a traveler measures a layover in minutes or hours, a connection in freight operations is measured in days, as cars sit on sidings or in railyards awaiting trains going their way. With reciprocal switching, a car may require multiple connections just to begin its journey. For instance, one train might pick up the car from the shipper and drop it at a serving yard while another takes it to the interchange, and then the competing railroad picks up the car at the interchange and takes it to another serving yard, where it gets put on a long-haul train. The car may be shuffled between several more trains, and each transfer is time- and resource-intensive.
Reciprocal switching can add as much as three days to the duration of the trip while making it less predictable. The biggest source of delivery time uncertainty is the connection between trains, and reciprocal switching would increase that. For a railroad operating near capacity, a missed connection could delay its own cars (and the ones it carries for its competitor) for days until a train with space arrives. Failing that, the railroad would need to “bump” traffic to accommodate the car, which would slow other cars in the network and degrade service elsewhere.
Reciprocal switching creates a moral hazard problem. The incumbent railroad incurs a high opportunity cost because the reciprocal switch slows its own deliveries and reduces how much it can transport effectively. That, in turn, affects its finances, including recovering fixed costs. For that reason, the incumbent will have an incentive to provide poor service to the shipper that is requiring the switch, in the hope of driving off that customer. It is highly unlikely the STB-sanctioned payment for performing the switch will counterbalance that disincentive; the incumbent will likely be paid a fraction of what the competing railroad receives, reflecting the proportion of the trip that it undertook.
Complex and costly / Reciprocal switching is costly for a railroad. Rail cars are effectively stuck on a one-dimensional track: for one car to move to another train requires that there be multiple tracks as well as a junction between them with a reversal of direction. With a reciprocal switch, this activity must take place at the industry location, at the first railroad’s serving yard (where cars are collected), at the interchange connecting the two railroads, and again at a serving yard of the second railroad.
Rail cars are heavy, weighing as much as 100 tons fully loaded, and each move requires a locomotive. Locomotives are almost never at an industry location on their own; rather, they are invariably pulling a train from which they must be decoupled to perform this car movement, and then reattached.
The car must be put in a siding or railyard akin to a parking lot where there are other cars to maneuver around, which is no easy task in a congested railyard. Finally, another train must come and pick it up, following many of those same steps.
This is merely the beginning of the process. Depending on the configuration of yards and interchange tracks, these steps may need to be repeated multiple times. Each switch is labor-intensive and slows the ultimate delivery of the goods on the train involved.
Productivity losses / A railroad would like to move as much freight as possible at the top safe speed with as few stops as possible. Train cars that sit in rail yards for an extended period or travel empty reduce how much a railroad effectively transports. Reciprocal switching would reduce rail velocity — the rate at which trains and cars move across the network — in multiple ways.
Reciprocal switching directly affects the assets used in service. Reciprocally switched cars must spend more time on sidings, and locomotives on those trains spend more time handling those cars, reducing their use in other services.