To see the possibility for such adaptation, consider U.S. corn production. Evidence indicates that the deleterious effect of extreme heat on corn results from water stress. Thus the most obvious adaptation for corn growers would be greater use of irrigation. When Tianyi Zhang et al. looked at agricultural production for corn, soybeans, and wheat over the period 1981–2012 in central U.S. counties where there is a mix of both irrigated and rain-fed fields, they found that irrigated corn and soybean fields were much less sensitive to episodes of extreme heat than were rain-fed fields. Irrigation eliminated about two-thirds of the negative effect of episodes of extreme heat for corn and soybeans. (The authors did not find similar successful use of irrigation for wheat.)
Irrigation is not the only possible adaptation. Looking at corn yields for the period 1981–2012 in eastern (non-irrigated) states, Ethan Butler and Peter Huybens found that whereas an increase in extreme temperature days (what they call “killing degree days”) had an adverse effect on crucial grain-filling stages in northern states, those same days increased the grain-filling period in southern states. Butler and Huybens note that corn hybrids in southern states are more effective in ameliorating the effect of extreme temperatures on corn yields.
Why haven’t northern farmers adopted the same techniques as their southern counterparts? Butler and Huybens speculate that southern methods of growing corn—planting about a month earlier and using tropical or temperate-tropical varieties—may only be “physiologically feasible” under “warmer conditions, possibly because of a longer growing season.” In other words, they answer that it may be feasible for northern corn farmers to change corn types and planting schedules only when the northern states’ climate—meaning average temperatures and the length of the growing season—more closely resembles that of the southern states.
If such a change in climate would occur, then economic history teaches that northern farmers would almost surely adopt the practices now pursued by southern farmers, significantly lessening the effect of temperature extremes on corn yield. As explained by Alan Olmstead and Paul Rhode, when American settlers spread wheat cultivation westward to the Great Plains in the latter part of the 19th century, they encountered a much drier climate with much greater variation in winter and summer temperatures. Mistaking unusually wet years during the 1880s as the norm, early wheat cultivations ended in abject failure. By the time of the first reliable wheat variety survey in 1919, however, farmers in the Great Plains grew almost entirely hard red spring and winter wheats that had been unknown to North America prior to the 1850s. Adaptation to the radically different Great Plains climate took decades, but eventually succeeded.
Models that calculate the current relationship between temperature and rainfall capture—at best—only the optimal adaptations of farmers to existing climatological conditions. The more dramatically future temperatures will change, the more dramatic will be the change in northern farming practices. Predicting adaptation to radically different future climate regimes cannot be done from models based on historical data.
“Climate and…” / While empirical studies of the effect of climate on agriculture tell us little about possible future long-term adaptation to changing climate, they at least include other causes of variation in agricultural output besides temperature. Such controls are often absent from highly publicized and influential studies of the effect of climate on non-agricultural damages.
One prominent example is the relation between climate and climate-related diseases such as malaria. One can find published studies that posit a simple relationship between average temperature, precipitation, and malaria. The studies conclude that if temperatures increase, then malaria incidence will increase.
But estimates of the short-run cross-sectional relationship between malaria and temperature are not relevant to estimates of long-term climate change and malaria incidence. Peter Gething and colleagues examined global malaria endemicity between 1900 and 2007 and found a “decoupling” of the climate-malaria relationship over the 20th century. They concluded that non-climatic factors—such as direct disease control and the indirect effect of urbanization and economic development—were much more important in explaining the declining geographic extent and intensity of malaria worldwide during the 20th century than was climate.
Lena Huldén and colleagues find that while increases in national per-capita income do have a large effect in reducing malaria rates, the biggest decrease came from reducing the average size of the household below four. Most strikingly, when other variables such as income and latitude were controlled, an increase in mean annual temperature actually decreased malaria frequency, while use of the pesticide DDT had a negative effect only when household size was not included as an explanatory variable.
The relationship between climate and disease is only one of many such “climate and…” relationships that have been empirically estimated using techniques that have a much too narrow and short-term focus to provide useful inferences about climate change and damages. For example, Marshall Burke and colleagues estimate a positive relationship between rising temperatures and the incidence of civil war. In subsequent work with the same dataset, however, Halvard Buhaug found that the result depended entirely on using country dummy variables (country fixed effects) as a proxy for country-specific explanations for civil war and a time-trend variable that did not vary across countries. When Buhaug dropped those from the regressions, temperature was no longer statistically significant; even when the country fixed effects and time variable were included, temperature explained less than 1 percent of the variance in civil war incidence. When Buhaug looked at a much larger set of civil wars—including armed intrastate conflicts with fewer than 1,000 deaths per year—and included not just average temperature but also temperature shocks (measured as deviations from annual means), he found that civil war risk increased as national GDP per capita declined, as the share of the population excluded from political influence increased, and that baseline risk of civil war in sub-Saharan Africa jumped with the collapse of the cold war system. These results were consistent with what political scientists had already discovered about the determinants of civil war in sub-Saharan Africa, but would be missed in a study that focused too narrowly on climate alone.
Perhaps the most serious problem in many simple “climate and…” empirical studies is that they fail to consider how underlying policies have contributed to determining the observed effect of climate. If one does not isolate the effect of policy and policy change on climate change, then one will fail to see that policy change itself is one way to alter the future effect of climate.
One of the most widely cited papers ever published on climate change effects is a simple regression by A.L. Westerling and colleagues showing a positive and statistically significant relationship between average summer temperatures and the number of large (500 hectares or bigger) wildfires in the western United States. But as Jonathan Klick and I pointed out in a 2012 paper, U.S. policy regarding wildfires underwent a dramatic transformation during the 1970–2010 period studied by Westerling and colleagues. The U.S. Forest Service (the agency with primary wildland fire-fighting responsibility) moved from a longstanding policy of putting out every wildland fire as quickly as possible to one where the first response to wildfires in more remote, higher-elevation mountain locations was to allow the fire to burn if it did not threaten human habitations. Thus the omission of a variable measuring policy change would be expected to bias the estimated relationship between summertime average temperature and the number of western wildfires. When we included such a policy variable in regressions explaining the incidence of large western wildfires, they found that summertime temperature had a smaller effect on wildfire incidence.
Another important policy change that affects agricultural output is crop insurance. Farmers can increase the yield of water-sensitive crops such as corn and soybeans by practicing conservation tillage—practices that leave more crop residue on the field after harvest. But the provision of subsidized crop insurance reduces the incentives of farmers to engage in such practices. During precisely the period of late 20th century warming in surface temperatures, roughly 1980–2010, the U.S. Congress greatly increased both the coverage of federal crop insurance and disaster payments, with major expansions in crop insurance subsidies in 1980, 1994, and 2000. According to Karina Schoengold and colleagues, a substantial body of research concludes that crop insurance incentivizes farmers to plant more acres and reduce costly risk-reducing crop rotations. When they carefully controlled for this, they found that over the period 1990–2004, when insurance and disaster payments are included as explanatory variables, the number of recent drought years actually decreased the use of no-till and other conservation tillage practices.
While the work by Schoengold and colleagues looked at episodes of drought, Schlenker extended his own work on the effect of extreme temperature on corn and soybean yield to control for the fraction of the crop that was federally insured. He found results that are consistent with those obtained by Schoengold and colleagues. The sensitivity of corn yields to extreme heat was 67 percent larger for insured corn than uninsured corn, and 43 percent larger for insured soybeans versus uninsured soybeans.
Flawed and arbitrary SCC estimates, which likely overstate warming costs, are already being used in Regulatory Impact Analyses that justify greenhouse gas emission regulation under the Clean Air Act.
Disaster aid and crop insurance insulate farmers from damage that occurs during drought and cut their incentive to adapt to episodes of drought and extreme heat. Omitting such policies from empirical studies of the effect of drought and extreme heat on agricultural output confounds bad policy with the direct effect of climate change.
THE SCC AND CLIMATE CHANGE POLICY
As researchers increasingly recognize that climate is only one of many important factors contributing to various measures of human well-being, SCC estimates based on such empirical work are likely to continue to fall. The problem, however, is that flawed and arbitrary SCC estimates, which likely overstate warming costs and therefore the marginal benefits of GHG emission reductions, are already being used in Regulatory Impact Analyses that justify GHG emission regulation under the Clean Air Act. This represents a failure on the part of the institutions responsible for developing and then auditing the SCC as an estimate of the benefits of GHG emission reduction.
Nowhere in the IWG technical support documents on the SCC does one find an attempt to open the hood on IAM estimates and ask whether they have sound economic foundations. Instead, the IWG runs IAMs under various assumptions regarding the discount rate and future climate sensitivity, thus producing a continuous distribution of SCC estimates. This is better than just producing point estimates, but of limited policy usefulness because the point estimates are still there, to be used in cost-benefit analysis.
One might have thought that the recent National Academy of Sciences panel reviewing the IWG’s SCC estimates might have remedied this by taking a close look at the economic foundations (or lack thereof) for the estimates. But the NAS report does not do this. Indeed, the most thorough and informative part of the report is the discussion of the physical science of climate sensitivity estimates. The economic analysis is otherwise quite similar to the IWG’s own analysis and, unsurprisingly, the NAS report concludes that there is no reason to update SCC estimates used in regulatory cost-benefit analyses.
There is every reason to be optimistic about advances in the economic analysis of the role of climate as a factor influencing human well-being. There is, unfortunately, much less reason to be optimistic that those advances will influence the cost-benefit analysis of climate change policy. To the extent that career EPA officials have a normative commitment to GHG emission reduction, they will obstruct a continuous process of SCC revisions that might weaken the case for such emission reductions. Even if some future IWG were to reduce SCC estimates, such a revision would not in and of itself legally require revision of major GHG emission regulations justified (in part) by earlier, higher SCC estimates.
Judicial scrutiny / One might wonder whether the federal courts might play a role in forcing adaptive revision of SCC estimates. Although academic commentators decry the trend, some prominent federal courts have become much less deferential than they traditionally have been to agency determinations of technical matters such as cost-benefit analysis. In cases such as Business Roundtable v. SEC, the courts have closely scrutinized agency cost-benefit analyses, critically analyzing not only the agency’s own presentation of costs and benefits, but also sometimes the weight the agency attached to peer-reviewed scientific work that raised skepticism of the case for regulation. It is possible that a federal court would similarly scrutinize SCC estimates if they were used by the EPA to justify future GHG emission reduction rules as reducing a substantial risk to human health and welfare.
In the climate change arena, however, such a possibility seems remote. When it comes to GHG emission reduction regulations, the federal courts have been extremely deferential to anything that the EPA says about climate science. It is true that last year, in Michigan v. EPA, the Supreme Court struck down EPA regulations requiring reductions in mercury emissions from power plants. But that was because the EPA argued that it could determine whether such reductions were “appropriate” (the statutory standard) without considering their cost. The SCC estimate is only one of many measures the EPA has adduced to show that there are benefits from GHG emission reduction. The question is when, if ever, federal courts will actually inquire into the methodologies the EPA and IWG have used to compute those benefits.
If the agencies and the courts will not intervene, the only feasible institutional pathways for change are Congress and the executive branch. The executive branch, in the form of the Office and Management and Budget (and in particular the Office of Information and Regulatory Affairs), might prepare revised estimates of the benefits and costs of existing GHG emission regulations based on newly published SCC estimates. Were an administration so inclined, it could take those estimates to Congress and mount a case for the passage of a statute requiring the EPA to consider the new SCC estimates in revising existing GHG emission reduction regulations—or else a statute specifically changing existing regulations. Whether an administration would ever initiate such a process, let alone its outcome, would require the alignment of future political interests that are highly unpredictable.
The long and short of this analysis is that, however much SCC estimates might improve over time with further work by both economists and physical scientists, those being used now, when GHG emission regulations are being promulgated, might be the only ones that will ever face court scrutiny. If initial SCC estimates suffice to allow GHG emission regulations to survive both OMB and judicial review, then for practical purposes it might never make any difference how wrong those initial SCC estimates might have been. Even if economists discovered that the earlier FUND IAM model was actually correct, with positive net benefits—that is, a negative SCC—from global warming up to about 2°C, that new knowledge might have no influence on policy. Whatever influence it has on policy will depend entirely on the ability to transmit its central message to political actors in the executive branch and Congress.
Readings
- “A Farmer’s View of the Ricardian Approach to Measuring Agricultural Effects of Climate Change,” by Roy Darwin. Climate Change, Vol. 41 (1999).
- A Question of Balance: Weighing the Options on Global Warming Policies, by William D. Nordhaus. Yale University Press, 2008.
- “Average Household Size and the Eradication of Malaria,” by Lena Huldén, Ross McKitrick, and Larry Huldén. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, Series A (2013).
- “Climate Change and the Global Malaria Recession,” by Peter W. Gething, David L. Smith, Anand P. Patil, Andrew J. Tatem, Robert W. Snow, and Simon I. Hay. Nature, Vol. 465 (2010).
- “Climate Not to Blame for African Civil Wars,” by Halvard Buhaug. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, Vol. 107, No. 16477 (2010).
- “Cost-Benefit Analysis of Financial Regulation: Case Studies and Implications (revised 2014),” by John C. Coates IV. Yale Law Journal, Vol. 124, No. 4 (Jan.–Feb. 2015).
- “Current Irrigation Practices in the Central United States Reduce Drought and Extreme Heat Impacts for Maize and Soybean, but Not for Wheat,” by Tianyi Zhang, Xiaomao Lin, and Gretchen F. Sassenrath. Science Total Environment, Vol. 508 (2015).
- “DICE 2013R: Introduction and User’s Manual 11–12,” by William D. Nordhaus and Paul Sztorc. 2013.
- “Estimates of the Social Cost of Carbon: Concepts and Results from the DICE-2013R Model and Alternative Approaches,” by William Nordhaus. Journal of the Association of Environmental & Resource Economists, Vol. 1, No. 1 (2014).
- “Estimating the Social Cost of Carbon for Use in U.S. Federal Rulemakings: A Summary and Interpretation,” by Michael Greenstone, Elizabeth Kopits, and Ann Wolverton. MIT Economics Department Working Paper 11–04, 2011.
- “Federal Crop Insurance and the Disincentives to Adapt to Extreme Heat,” by Francis Annan and Wolfram Schlenker. Columbia University working paper, 2014.
- “Fire Suppression Policy, Weather, and Western Wildland Fire Trends: An Empirical Analysis,” by Jason Scott Johnston and Jonathan Klick. In Wildfire Policy: Law and Economics Perspectives, edited by Karen Bradshaw and Dean Lueck; Routledge, 2012.
- Lukewarming, by Patrick Michaels and Paul Knappenberger. Cato Institute, 2015.
- “Nonlinear Temperature Effects Indicate Severe Damages to U.S. Crop Yields under Climate Change,” by W. Schlenker and M.J. Roberts. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, Vol. 106 (2009).
- “Responding to Climatic Challenges: Lessons from U.S. Agricultural Development,” by Alan L. Olmstead and Paul W. Rhode. In The Economics of Climate Change: Adaptations Past and Present, edited by Gary Libecap and Richard Steckel; National Bureau of Economic Research, 2011.
- “The Critical Role of Extreme Heat for Maize Production in the United States,” by David B. Lobell, Graeme L. Hammer, Greg McLean, Carlos Messina, Michael J. Roberts, and Wolfram Schlenker. Nature Climate Change, Vol. 3 (2013).
- “The Economic Impact of Climate Change,” by Richard S. Tol. Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 23, No. 2 (2009).
- “The Impact of Ad Hoc Disaster and Crop Insurance Programs on the Use of Risk-Reducing Conservation Tillage Practices,” by Karina Schoengold, Ya Ding, and Russell Headlee. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 97 (2014).
- “The Impact of Global Warming on Agriculture: a Ricardian Analysis,” by Robert Mendelsohn, William D. Nordhaus, and David Shaw. American Economic Review, Vol. 84, No. 4 (1994).
- “The Implications for Climate Sensitivity of AR5 Forcing and Heat Uptake Estimates,” by Nicholas Lewis and Judith A. Curry. Climate Dynamics, Vol. 45, No. 3 (2015).
- “Transient Temperature Response Modeling in IAMs: The Effects of Over Simplification on the SCC,” by Alex L. Marten. Economics E‑Journal, No. 2011–18 (Oct. 20, 2011).
- “Variations in the Sensitivity of U.S. Maize Yield to Extreme Temperatures by Region and Growth Phase,” by Ethan E. Butler and Peter Huybers. Environmental Research Letters, Vol. 10, No. 3 (2015).
- “Warming and Earlier Spring Increase Western U.S. Forest Wildfire Activity,” by A.L. Westerling, H. Hidalgo, D.R. Cayan, and T.L. Swetnam. Science, Vol. 313, No. 940 (2006).
- “Warming Increases the Risk of Civil War in Africa,” by Marshall B. Burke, Edward Miguel, Shankar Satyanath, John A. Dykema, and David B. Lobell. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, Vol. 106, No. 20670 (2009).
- Warming the World: Economic Models of Global Warming, by William D. Nordhaus and Joseph Boyer. MIT Press, 2000.
- “Will U.S Agriculture Really Benefit from Global Warming? Accounting for Irrigation in the Hedonic Approach,” by W. Schlenker, W.M. Hanemann and A.C. Fisher. American Economic Review, Vol 95, No. 1 (2005).