Poor Justifications
Despite their obvious failings, energy subsidies—most notably for renewable sources like wind-propelled generation—continue to be justified in a number of ways. The most commonly heard arguments from renewable energy proponents have been, “We just need a little more time to become fully competitive,” and, “Two wrongs do, in fact, make a right.” More recently, proponents have added “green jobs” and economic development arguments, as if subsidized renewable energy could provide economic salvation. None of those arguments are valid.
The first justification is just the latest incarnation of the “infant industry” argument first made by Alexander Hamilton over two centuries ago. This argument asserts that renewable generation simply needs more time to innovate and reduce its costs to be fully competitive with fossil generation, at which point it will become a viable, welfare-enhancing industry. But renewable generation has been subsidized heavily for 35 years, ever since President Carter signed the Public Utilities Regulatory Policy Act and the Energy Tax Act in 1978. With passage of the Energy Policy Act of 1992 and creation of both the investment tax credit (ITC) and the production tax credit (PTC), these subsidies increased. The PTC currently stands at 2.2 cents per kilowatt-hour (kWh) on an after-tax basis. Based on the current 35 percent corporate tax rate, that translates into a before-tax credit of 3.4 cents per kWh, often larger than the wholesale price of electricity.
The second justification is simply a version of the “It’s not fair!” argument, which parents know well. Renewable generation advocates argue that conventional generation has been subsidized for over a century; therefore, renewable generation deserves its subsidies, too, because that’s only fair. While some forms of generation are subsidized indirectly, such as the Price-Anderson Act’s limitation of nuclear plant owners’ liability for accidents, other subsidies are often associated with general provisions of the tax code, such as accelerated depreciation schedules and tax-exempt bond financing by municipalities. Whether such accounting treatments are “subsidies” can be debated, but they are given to all generating resources. Renewable generation is the only type of generation that benefits from guaranteed revenues, such as the PTC and state “renewable portfolio standard” (RPS) mandates to purchase such generation at above-market prices.
The third and most recent justification, that economic salvation lies along a subsidized “green-energy” path, is not only a last refuge of the market-interventionist scoundrel, it has been discredited by experience. Not for nothing have countries such as Spain and Germany learned that green energy extracts a heavy economic price in the form of skyrocketing electric rates that damage other industries. Here in the United States, the promise of a new green energy economy is littered with the bankrupt remains of many companies that had received large checks from the U.S. Department of Energy, thanks to political connections and not technological and economic advantage.
Low-Value Electricity
Unlike other commodities, the value of electricity varies constantly in response to continuous changes in supply and demand. Consequently, the market value of electricity is always changing, from thousands of dollars per megawatt-hour in times of extreme electric demand, to below zero when markets are flooded with electricity supplies from generating resources, like nuclear plants, that cannot be turned on and off quickly or costlessly.
The constant change in market values, and the influence of subsidized wind generation on those values, reveals one of the greatest deficiencies of wind generation, and one of the reasons why subsidizing wind generation is grossly inefficient: wind produces low-value electricity. To understand why this is so, it helps to understand how the demand for electricity is met using a combination of baseload, intermediate, and peaking generating resources. Baseload generators, such as nuclear plants, have high capital costs but low variable operating costs. Accordingly, they are designed to run continuously, every hour of every day. Peaking generators, often oil- or natural gas–fired simple-cycle generators, operate when electricity demand is greatest, such as during hot and humid weather. Peaking units have relatively low capital costs, but high variable costs. For example, in New York City there are several very old and inefficient oil-fired generating plants. Because they are so expensive to operate, it is only when electricity demand is at its highest that they run.
Figure 1 provides an example. The heavy black line is called a “load duration curve” and represents electricity demand (load) at every hour, ordered from the highest demand hour to the lowest demand hour. Baseload generators, B, operate in all 8,760 hours of the year. There are two types of intermediate generators, I1, which operate a total of HI‑1 hours during the year, and I2, which is assumed to have a higher variable cost and thus operates HI‑2 hours during the year. Finally, there are peaking resources P, which operate the least amount, HP hours, during the year. The number of hours during the year when each type of unit operates will be chosen to meet demand in every hour at the lowest possible cost.