A third driver of renegotiations is the poor contractual allocation of exogenous demand risk. The standard PPP funded by user fees is a fixed-term contract awarded to the firm that bids the lowest user fee for a given term. Because demand is stochastic, a fixed-term contract assigns most of the demand risk to the concessionaire. This makes sense when the infrastructure is, for example, a container terminal, where demand responds to effort by the concessionaire. But demand for roads, bridges, and tunnels depends mostly on exogenous factors such as macroeconomic activity, a variable whose forecasts are notoriously unreliable. Thus, in a fixed-term contract, the winning bid internalizes exogenous risk by asking for a user fee that generates enough additional expected revenue to compensate for demand risk.
The general principle is that exogenous demand risk should be borne by the party best able to bear it. If the concessionaire assumes demand risk, taxpayers are in fact purchasing insurance against an exogenous risk, which they would bear under public provision. This is not cost-effective. Indeed, in practice, when using fixed-term contracts, governments need to pledge minimum revenue guarantees in order to make projects bankable. Moreover, fixed-term contracts tend to be renegotiated in times of severe economic stress, as is occurring presently because of the COVID pandemic, which shifts risk from the concessionaire to the government.
Usually, having a private party face demand risk is a way to ensure that the firm will try to attract demand, for example, by good maintenance in the case of infrastructure. However, in the case of highways and other transport infrastructure, the degree of competition usually is limited. Moreover, the service quality provided by a road, tunnel, or bridge can be contracted and enforced, so having the concessionaire bear demand risk serves no purpose.
Thus, for these projects, a PVR contract can be used to shield the concessionaire from exogenous demand risk, replicating the demand risk allocation of a standard non-PPP infrastructure project — that is, traditional provision. Under a PVR contract, the regulator sets the discount rate and user fee schedule, and firms bid the present value of user fee revenue they require to finance, build, operate, and maintain the infrastructure. The firm that makes the lowest bid wins the auction and the franchise ends when the present value of user fees collected equals the winning bid. The term of the concession automatically adjusts to demand shocks, limiting the demand risk borne by the concessionaire.
TABLE 3 Renegotiations in Chile: Before and After the 2010 Reform |
|
HIGHWAYS |
TRANSPORT |
|
Number |
Percent of investment |
Number |
Percent of investment |
Before the reform |
29 |
26.1% |
44 |
27.6% |
After the reform |
15 |
0.7% |
25 |
0.9% |
The PVR contract has several advantages. First, it reduces risk because demand fluctuations and their associated revenue variations lead to a longer or shorter contract term. Indeed, we have estimated using Chilean data that, relative to a fixed-term contract, the risk premium reduction with a PVR contract is around 30% of investment. More generally, PVR contracts may be viewed as having a built-in renegotiation clause that is triggered by low demand realizations. When demand is lower than expected, the contract length extends automatically and total revenues for the firm, in present value, are unaffected. In contrast, with fixed-term PPPs there is no need for contract renegotiations. Less risk also implies that minimum revenue guarantees are no longer required to make the project bankable.
Second, with a PVR contract, the government has the option to unilaterally buy back the concession by paying a fair price for the contract, i.e., without regulatory takings. This price is equal to the difference between the bid and the present value of toll revenue already collected. Because the concessionaire’s winning bid determines the total amount of present value revenues it will receive, the PVR contract is closer to a complete contract than a fixed-term contract. A fair value for an early buy-back option can be calculated at any moment by using standard accounting information.
Third, a PVR contract allows flexibility in setting user fees. This can be valuable for urban highways because user fees can be adjusted for congestion without affecting the present value of revenues for the concessionaire, as long as changes in user fees do not threaten the possibility of obtaining the bid revenue. In the case of a fixed-term PPP, the flexibility to change user fees would increase the revenue and political risk facing the franchise-holder.
Figure 1 shows the cumulative investment in transport PPPs in Chile since the PPP program was launched in 1993 with the El Melón tunnel. As can be seen in the figure, initially all PPPs were fixed term. The first PVR contract was auctioned in 1998, but after 2006 PVR contracts became the norm. Note that a third type of contract — the so-called “revenue distribution mechanism” — appeared in 2002. These were five fixed-term PPPs that were renegotiated and turned into variable-term contracts in 2002 after their revenue plummeted following the 1997 Asian financial crisis and the subsequent collapse in public revenues and exports. By 2017, 29 of the 66 PPPs awarded were variable-term contracts. The cumulative investment in transport PPPs in Chile exceeded $12 billion. Some 55% of all investment had been made with (or turned into) variable-term contracts.
Table 4 compares renegotiations under fixed-term contracts and under PVR for highway PPPs in Chile. The table reports the value of renegotiations as a fraction of the initial investment, both during construction as well as during the first eight years of operation. The table shows that renegotiated amounts under PVR have been about one-tenth of the amounts under the fixed-term contracts. This is consistent with concessionaires having fewer incentives to renegotiate contracts because low demand realizations have little or no effect on their bottom line.