This would be of little importance except for the vast amount of land involved. In the lower 48 states, public lands encompass nearly 475 million acres, 21% of the land mass and more than the combined areas of France, Spain, Sweden, and Norway. (See Figure 1.) Adding the public lands in Alaska and Hawaii brings the total to about 640 million acres, 28% of the U.S. land area. Most citizens are unaware of just how large is the federal estate.
The Costs of Federal Land Ownership
There are several reasons why government ownership of this huge resource is detrimental to economic welfare and individual liberty. First off, it is in sharp contrast to the plans of the nation’s founders and philosophical forebears. The importance of private ownership of land for advancing individual potential and autonomy, as well as land value, was emphasized by early political economists and philosophers, including Adam Smith, John Locke, Jeremy Bentham, Jean-Jacques Rousseau, John Stuart Mill, David Ricardo, Edward Wakefield, and Robert Torrens. The advantages of widespread private land ownership were championed by Thomas Jefferson, who claimed that “the earth is given as a common stock for man to labor and live on…. The small landholders are the most precious part of a state.” As he toured the new country in 1835, Alexis de Tocqueville observed that being freeholders changed the way in which Americans thought of themselves and the country’s political structure. The noted historian of the frontier Frederick Jackson Turner asserted in 1893 that America ultimately was shaped by private ownership and small-farm frontier settlement as the underpinnings for democracy, an independent citizenry, and generalized economic wellbeing.
In contrast, in the more modern period, the threats of private ownership for an authoritarian government were clearly understood by Karl Marx, Vladimir Lenin, Joseph Stalin, and Mao Zedong. They banned private property in land and placed it in state possession, jailing or executing previous owners. Even today in China, where private rights to intangible property such as stocks and bonds are tolerated, long-term, fee-simple title to land is prohibited. The state remains dominant in holding the most critical resources as its own.
From the colonial period through the late 19th century, the overriding aim of government land policies was to transfer land ownership as quickly as possible from the state to private citizens. The attraction of America for immigrants was land. And they could get it in comparatively small parcels that supported individual farms. The Homestead Act of 1862 distributed federal land in 160-acre plots for free to claimants, and between 1863 and 1920 some nearly three million homestead claims were filed for more than 435 million acres, smaller than the government’s holdings today but larger than Alaska.
A land demarcation system was created to facilitate the measurement, location, trade, and productive use of land. The frontier societies that emerged were among the most egalitarian in the world. Capital gains from land ownership and sale were the primary sources of wealth creation, and the use of land as collateral encouraged widespread participation in and growth of capital markets. Agricultural production expanded and prosperous communities emerged. Private citizens with a stake in society invested in local public goods provision, particularly education, so that the United States became a world leader in general access to a practical education. Such a society was politically stable.
The long-standing emphasis on the private acquisition of government lands, however, ended in the late 19th century. In its place came the creation of the National Forests, now comprising more than 225 million acres, and the National Rangelands, covering almost 250 million acres, along with a permanent bureaucracy for administration and short-term distribution. As of Fiscal Year 2018, the USFS has some 37,000 career, tenured civil service employees and a budget of $1.75 billion, and the BLM has over 8,000 career employees and a budget of $1.1 billion.
Lost economic value / A second reason why so much land ownership by the state is detrimental is that much of it is misallocated and dramatically under-produces, diminishing general welfare. Much poorer developing countries seek to have their natural resources provide employment and output for their citizens, but the United States locks more and more federal land away, ostensibly for preservation for future generations. There is no clear metric for assessing how those generations will benefit nor are the tradeoffs easily available for general citizens to assess. Decisions are determined by politicians and the bureaucracy in response to lobby pressures, and no party in that process bears direct costs from the associated resource allocation and use decisions.
This is not to say that areas of high amenity or cultural values should not be set aside. This description, however, does not characterize most of the federal lands. Currently, the National Park Service in the Department of the Interior administers a comparatively small 27 million acres in the lower 48 states and 80 million acres (12% of the total federal lands) in the United States overall, as national parks, national monuments, national preserves, national historic sites, national recreation areas, and national battlefields.
There are no aggregate measures of the opportunity costs resulting from mismanagement and allocation. Evidence suggests, however, that the costs could be very large given the size of the federal estate. Consider that while oil and natural gas production have jumped dramatically on private lands over the past 10 years, on federal lands output has been static or declining, even with favorable geologic deposits.
Similarly, timber production from the National Forests has fallen sharply to levels not observed since the 1930s, even though lumber prices are rising. Higher lumber prices contribute to upward shifts in housing costs that are of concern to many because of their equity implications. Poorer members of society are increasingly unable to afford to own homes.
Where comparable data exist in the Pacific Northwest, it is possible to examine output on private lands versus the National Forests. Timber harvest from federal lands has fallen, while harvest from private lands in the region is the primary source of output. Withholding timber stands does not make them more valuable. As timber stands age, they grow more slowly, block new tree growth, and become more vulnerable to disease. It is often argued that the National Forests should be more aggressively thinned than they are now to better conserve scarce western water supplies and reduce the incidence and growth of wildfires.
Finally, as with other productive uses, livestock grazing on federal lands has declined for nearly 50 years. The negative economic effect of reduced grazing on rangelands, particularly, is concentrated in semi-arid regions where there are few other land-use options and the federal share of land ownership is large. For example, the BLM administers 85% of Nevada, 57% of Utah, and nearly 50% or more of Arizona, Idaho, and Oregon. With greater uncertainty associated with approval and maintenance of the grazing permits that ranchers depend upon, the lands’ economic value has fallen. Ranches have gone into foreclosure or been consolidated. Rural communities tied to ranching and lumbering have withered as the economic base surrounding them has deteriorated. As a result, opportunities for the young have plummeted, encouraging out-migration to urban areas. The relative weakening of rural economies and population declines are of growing concern in policy circles.
Locking away more land / As administrative reallocation and regulatory controls have led to the fall in the productive use of federal lands, more land has been placed into various types of preservation and recreation. Is this optimal? How much land should be locked away? Only a rich country could afford to set aside so much valuable real estate. This luxury could be temporary, however, if the costs rise and become more apparent to citizens.
To get a sense of what might be at stake, consider the decision to withhold oil and gas exploration and production in the 19 million-acre Arctic National Wildlife Reserve in Alaska since 1977. With reserves of 7.06 billion barrels of oil, priced at (a comparatively conservative) $50 per barrel, the estimated opportunity costs are $251 billion, a present value of $1,141 per adult citizen. Across the entire federal lands, the costs of preserving so much land are apt to be orders of magnitude higher. Such losses likely affect gross domestic product growth, employment opportunities, and welfare for the overall population.
With competitive markets, private land is reallocated across uses routinely as prices shift on the margin. Land moves to its highest-valued use. Critical private lands needed for public infrastructure investment, preservation, or protection of amenity values can be acquired by the government. Proposed expenditures can be weighed against alternatives. Political/bureaucratic allocation and management of lands already owned by the state, however, do not work in this manner. Multiple constituent groups, ranging from environmental and recreational organizations to historic users—ranchers, timber companies, minerals and oil and gas producers—appear before congressional hearings and before the agencies to lobby for their favored policies. Outcomes depend upon the strength of the lobby group, whether they face competitors, and how politicians and agency officials respond to them. Cost–benefit analysis of bureaucratic decisions, where used, often is not transparent and agency decisions are cloaked in public-goods rhetoric. In this setting, citizens have little information to assess the net effect of the decisions made by the bureaucracy that manages the federal lands.
A third reason why federal land ownership is damaging is that the allocation and reallocation of so large a resource stock through the political/bureaucratic process is socially divisive. Reallocation is not routine, but lumpy. Constituent groups compete to enlist the coercive power of the state on their behalf. Losers, unlike sellers, are not compensated, and winners, unlike buyers, do not pay for the value of the resource. The losers resent the outcome and blame the winners, while the winners characterize past users and uses as inconsistent with the public interest. This process undermines social cohesion and civil discourse, both of which are essential for a functioning, stable democracy.
How Did the Federal Government Reserve so Much Land?
To understand how the federal government came to withhold so much land given the past emphasis on private ownership, it is useful to consider the U.S. settlement process in the late 19th century. As the frontier moved west of the 100th meridian, far different conditions were encountered from those to the east. The land was more rugged and semi-arid, making it less economically viable for small farming. Logging, ranching, and mineral production were more appropriate economic uses. Land laws such as the Homestead Act could have been modified to allow for much larger, non-farming distributions, but they were not.