Monetary economists have long advocated rules-based monetary policy to improve macroeconomic outcomes by limiting central bankers’ discretion. A problem with implementing this approach is that public officials do not want a strict rule that prevents them from changing their policy stance, especially when unforeseen circumstances arise. The 2015 Fed Oversight Reform and Modernization Act (FORM Act) was drafted to mitigate this problem. Had it passed, the bill would have required the Federal Reserve (Fed) to set a policy rule, only allowing the Fed to suspend the rule if it publicly explained its reasoning to Congress.1
Policy rules have been popular in the academic literature for decades. For instance, Milton Friedman famously argued in the 1960s for the Fed to adopt a zero nominal interest rate environment (often dubbed the Friedman rule).2 Rules-based monetary policy gained further popularity and academic significance when, in 1993, John Taylor found that a simple rule that adjusted the policy rate as a weighted response to inflation and the output gap (the difference between gross domestic product [GDP] and potential GDP) was able to closely match the realized federal funds rate.3 In the modern New Keynesian macroeconomic framework, interest rates are often modeled as a generalized feedback rule, similar in spirit to the 1993 Taylor rule but with different weights or modified components (replacing or adding to inflation and the output gap, for instance).