Second, government-to-government negotiations to eliminate subsidies haven’t borne much fruit. After the Great Recession, for example, attempts within the G20 and elsewhere to get governments to commit to limit trade-distorting subsidies proved “only minimally effective, mainly as a check against serious backsliding rather than a strict prohibition or springboard for real reform.” Today, basically no government has responded to Chinese, U.S., and other subsidies with an invitation to negotiate a multilateral pullback.
Third and most important are the political economy considerations: Politicians and rent-seeking interest groups often use foreign subsidies to justify their own demands for U.S. subsidies or import protection—measures they claim are essential to offset the “unfair” advantages bestowed on subsidized foreign competition. Without some sort of U.S. government response to those foreign subsidies, the political case for subsidies, tariffs, and other bad policies is stronger (if not irresistible), regardless of the economics. Sugar is a classic example in this regard: Florida Sen. Marco Rubio has justified his vote to protect the U.S. sugar program on the grounds that it is necessary to counteract foreign subsidies, and the industry has said U.S. subsidies should go only when all foreign ones go, too. Given the U.S. sugar program’s many harms, this argument makes no rational sense—but it does seem to move the political needle.
Similarly, foreign subsidies can also undermine key interest groups’ support for freer trade policies, especially trade agreements. Implementing these deals depends in large part on balancing pro-trade exporting companies and farm groups—eager to find new markets abroad and thus to lobby for free trade agreements (FTAs)—against U.S. firms and workers worried about import competition (and thus lobbying against the FTA). However, if a company or farmer that supported a U.S. FTA with country X then faces a flood of X’s subsidized imports two years later without the U.S. government doing something about it, that company/farmer will probably be less likely to support the next FTA with country Y. So might other companies/farmers watching that situation play out.
Thus, “doing nothing” might make for great economics, but, thanks to politics, it could mean even worse policy in the future—and we have plenty of evidence in just that regard.
So, What to Do?
Believe it or not, I’m persuaded by the political economy responses to the classic, “do nothing” approach to foreign subsidies and wrote as much in that old paper. That doesn’t mean, however, that Trump-style tariffs or countersubsidies are the correct response, for many of the reasons that Boudreaux and others cite—especially these measures’ inefficacy and susceptibility to corruption.
Fortunately, we have a third choice: the global anti-subsidy disciplines set forth in the World Trade Organization’s Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures (SCM Agreement). All 164 WTO members, including the United States and China, have agreed to abide by the SCM Agreement’s rules, which are intended to encourage international trade by both preventing the proliferation of trade-distorting subsidies and providing reasonable dispute-settlement mechanisms for adjudicating subsidy-related disputes. The SCM Agreement 1) defines what is and isn’t a “subsidy”; 2) prohibits the most trade-distorting subsidies (those tied to exports or the recipients’ use of local content over imports); 3) lets a WTO member challenge other subsidies (i.e., ones that harm the member’s domestic companies at home or in overseas markets) at the WTO or via a “countervailing duty” (CVD) investigation; and 4) sets forth procedures for CVD cases.
(For the uninitiated: in a CVD case, a national government agency investigates, usually at the request of a domestic company or union, whether imports of a certain product have been subsidized by a foreign government and are causing injury to the domestic industry making the same product. If the agency finds both subsidization/injury, it can impose remedial duties on the imports that are intended to offset the subsidies and thus level the playing field in the home market.)
The SCM Agreement isn’t an outright ban on all subsidies. Instead, it reflects a compromise among all WTO members, discouraging only the most distortive government subsidies while allowing members to utilize broad-based subsidies and limiting the protectionist administration of CVD laws by overzealous government agencies running the investigations. The U.S. administration of its CVD cases has flaws—ones that have gotten worse in the last decade and reflect some of the concerns that “do nothing” folks have raised. Too often, CVD cases produce duties on imports in excess of the level of subsidies found—turning what are supposed to be remedial import taxes into punitive ones. More importantly, U.S. CVD law has no safety valve for suspending cases or duties that, while technically justified under WTO rules, undermine bigger national economic goals. In the last few years, for example, the U.S. has slapped CVDs on numerous renewable energy products and housing construction materials, even as the government tries to increase Americans’ access to those very things. Nevertheless, unlike the U.S. anti-dumping law (which targets private pricing behavior and is utterly detached from any legitimate purpose), the CVD law has a reasonable foundation and should thus probably be reformed instead of scrapped entirely.
That said, global anti-subsidy rules’ alternative process—a WTO dispute—is a much better approach than unilateral CVDs. Most importantly, WTO cases are adjudicated by respected independent arbiters approved by all WTO members. That makes decisions mostly immune to domestic politics (and politically motivated provisions of national CVD laws) and more respected by WTO members, including those on the losing end of a dispute. Thus, as we’ve discussed, WTO cases have been relatively effective in getting members—including the United States and China—to abandon their offending measures. Also, as trade law guru Simon Lester just explained, WTO anti-subsidy disputes have a broader reach than CVD cases: litigation can involve more than just two countries; cases examine trade effects in any global market, not merely the market of the complaining government; and the rules envision remedies beyond just more (MOAR!) tariffs, thus giving the complainant “a greater ability to induce changes to the subsidy measures.” They can even get resolved via government-to-government consultations that must occur before litigation even commences.
The WTO system isn’t perfect—it’s too slow, and some of its rules could stand to be updated—but it still provides a better approach for governments interested in actually resolving foreign subsidy and related problems, rather than just finding an excuse for enriching a few domestic interest groups (and hurting American consumers and the economy in the process).
Summing It All Up
Global subsidies are a problem—and one that, for well-founded political reasons, can argue for governments doing more than just the economically solid “nothing.” Tariffs and other unilateral measures, however, come with their own big concerns and thus can often be a cure that’s worse than the disease. Fortunately, WTO anti-subsidy rules and disputes provide a third choice that, while still imperfect, can better address global subsidies’ distortions while avoiding unilateral remedies’ own pitfalls.
National CVDs are one way to enforce these rules, and—thanks to procedural and substantive disciplines imposed on their use and the clear availability of judicial review (domestic or at the WTO)—they’re certainly better than the opaque lawlessness of current and likely future U.S. tariff policy. One cheer, therefore, for the EU’s new CVD investigation of Chinese EVs, especially since the EU’s anti-subsidy law, unlike the United States’, has a “public interest” check to ensure that new duties don’t undermine more important strategic, economic, or social objectives. It would’ve been better for the EU to have taken its Chinese EV gripe to the WTO, but at least it hasn’t gone Full Trump/Biden/United Steelworkers just yet.
In general, governments haven’t embraced the WTO alternative to domestic CVD cases, with the latter still far more common than the former. Some of that preference is the system’s fault (e.g., for being too slow), but most systemic problems can be fixed by relatively simple reforms (via negotiations). The WTO’s more intractable problem is the members themselves, particularly the United States, which continues to block not only new appointments to the WTO’s Appellate Body (thus crippling the dispute system) but also broader reform negotiations. In fact, the Biden administration recently doubled down on this position, started during the Trump years when it threatened to maintain its WTO blockades if the EU dared restart its challenge to (bogus) U.S. “national security” tariffs on European steel and aluminum.
Chinese subsidies might still be worse for the global economy than current U.S. trade policy, but not by much.
Chart(s) of the Week
Tax compliance can’t balance the budget: