That might sound a mouthful and is perhaps too broad as a useful term in policy debates (think how many indicators you’d need to assess whether an economy had become more or less dynamic!)
It might therefore be easier to define it against its antithesis: induced stasis. A economy that is not dynamic is one where higher value-added opportunities remain underexplored or unexploited because resources cannot or do not move to these opportunities. That perhaps provides us with more clarity. Certain barriers or policies exist that restrict the flow of people, goods, or capital in ways that reduce the amount of market-tested exploration and, ultimately, innovation. Often this is deliberate, like policies to prevent a change in the feel of an area, or to “protect jobs,” or something else. If we are serious about improving “dynamism,” removing these obvious barriers should be our first focus.
If anyone has any further thoughts on how “economic dynamism” should be defined, please leave them in the comments.
Reagan’s lesson for Rishinomics?
My fellow Times columnist Danny Finkelstein uses the story of former Reagan Budget Director David Stockman to analogize that Trussonomics will suffer the same fate as Reaganomics: delivering tax cuts without ever getting political buy-in for offsetting spending cuts, so widening structural budget deficits.
Let’s leave aside for a second that Truss a) is planning merely to block Rishi Sunak’s very recent tax rises, not deeply cut taxes and b) has actually said she would do a spending review and would aim to keep the growth of state spending below the growth rate of the economy…Is the Reagan period, on the whole, such a terrifying prospect?
Stockman was right on Reagan’s tax cuts failing to “starve the beast” and reduce spending (although it still grew more slowly than pre-Reagan), but inflation fell during the Reagan years, contrary to Rishi’s predictions on the effects of the near-term widening of budget deficits. Yes, this was obviously because of Volker’s huge monetary disinflation that had already begun, and real interest rates did then remain fairly high even after this. But that’s the point I’ve been making about Rishi’s inflation claims: monetary policy dominates fiscal! Unless he thinks the Bank of England won’t do its job, it’s very misleading to imply higher deficits will lead axiomatically to inflation.
Sunak has pivoted more recently to warning about the risk of higher interest rates from tax cuts. In this view, tax cuts raise aggregate demand, causing an inflationary impulse that the Bank of England must offset. But even here, how much the larger Reagan structural deficits themselves actually *caused* elevated real interest rates the U.S. saw is more contested in the literature than I expected. Benjamin Friedman’s work is what people commonly cite to argue they played an important role, but many other decent economists seem to conclude they had little effect, especially relative to the Volker disinflation and fears of nuclear war. Other (now well-known) economists such as Larry Summers and Olivier Blanchard at the time suggested domestic deficits were not as important as other international factors in raising real rates too.
I have to admit, this literature jarred with my prior somewhat, which was that the bigger deficits would, all else equal, raise rates. Ultimately, I thought, the debate was whether a “looser fiscal, tighter monetary” stance would be better or worse economically judged by other metrics. But perhaps I should have been more skeptical about there being such a firm link. I mean, the Trump tax cut hardly led to a take-off in interest rates, nor did the UK’s vast post-financial crisis borrowing. The relationship between deficits and real rates seems a lot less obvious empirically than I once would have thought. There’s some theoretical reasons why, which we can perhaps touch on another week…
Yet if those who think there is a very strong relationship between deficits and rates really *do* believe that fiscal tightening can make the Bank of England’s job significantly easier and deliver more desirable results, why stop the tax rises at exactly where Sunak has planned? Why not eliminate the deficit entirely and run a surplus right now? Why not cut spending too? [That it wasn’t in a manifesto seems a weak get-out, given the manifesto ruled out raising national insurance rates too, which Sunak breached.] I don’t see any Sunak supporters arguing for any of this. So it seems more like a status quo bias. With the UK seemingly entering recession, would they even be proposing Sunak’s big tax rises now (particularly on corporation tax and marginal national insurance rates) if they weren’t already on the books?
Look, I still remain concerned about longer-term fiscal sustainability, but perhaps over time have become slightly less so about short-term borrowing. I wrote previously that Sunak’s corporation tax rise in lieu of COVID-19 debt was very premature given we didn’t know where the public finances would shake out. And if a looser fiscal policy for a couple of years helps grease the wheels for additional important supply-side tax and regulatory reforms, then I think it would be a price worth paying for Truss. Indeed, if Truss can get growth going as Reagan did after 1982, I suspect she’d be considered an extremely successful PM!
On Finkelstein’s central lesson, too, I wonder whether he has the analogy backwards. His major criticism is that Republicans like Stockman (Reagan’s budget director) delivered their promised deficit-expanding tax cuts first and then hoped to win support for spending cuts, which ultimately never came because Republican politicians opposed cutting government programs. I read this warning for Truss as: don’t ever do something that is expansionary unless you are certain you have the political backing to then ultimately finance it. And that’s a view I’ve been broadly sympathetic with: I have written in favor of a fiscal rule that would force politicians to raise taxes *first* for a number of years, before they could permanently increase spending.
Yet the problem for Rishi is that he delivered the Conservatives’ policy of promised extra NHS and social care spending, and indeed COVID-19 relief, without, ultimately, getting the enduring support from the party required for the permanent tax rises he tried to deliver. Indeed, the Tory manifesto in 2019 explicitly said they would not raise national insurance and said nothing about raising corporation tax or holding down income tax thresholds. In this election, his position is being trounced, making it clear now that the party rejects the package as a whole. Sunak introduced all these tax rises, then, without a rigorous mandate. If anyone risked worsening structural borrowing — in this case by raising spending without ensuring he actually had the buy-in to fund it sustainably — isn’t it the former Chancellor?