While it is unconstitutional to withhold promised funds to force a state to do something unrelated to the program funded, there is nothing inherently wrong with using carrots instead of sticks to incentivize reform. Still, some are upset with the White House’s meddling in local affairs. This instinct is almost always correct. But unlike much federal involvement at the local level, this plan directly targets rather than creates market inefficiencies.
While libertarians prize a strong federalism, state and local rules can create market failures too. There is no perfect formula for guarding against federal overreach while ensuring free markets, though voluntary federal programs are far from the worst-case scenario.
Here, it might just provide the breakthrough housing needs to overcome barriers that, while of local creation, are no less deleterious to the cause of market freedom — arguably more so even than eminent-domain actions, which these days are by no means owner-friendly.
Indeed, as George Mason University law professor Ilya Somin points out, the social and economic costs of local exclusionary zoning run such a wide gamut that “whether you’re a libertarian, a conservative property rights advocate, a racial justice crusader, a progressive concerned about economic inequality, or just someone who wants to lower housing prices … this is a cause you have good reason to support.”
Some will lament the loss of their suburb’s quietude, arguing this cost outweighs the benefits of easing zoning restrictions. While losing the suburbs’ arcadian ideal is a legitimate concern, the answer is not to use artificial means to foreclose change where the market otherwise demands it.
As the country faces a massive housing shortage, the time is long past for removing entry barriers that, when not perpetuating racial segregation, stifle growth on a scale that cannot be measured until the market is finally free to do its thing.
Some lawmakers have begun to recognize that the old rules do not jibe with the population, wants, and needs of 21st-century Americans, with trends headed only further away from the Levittown ideal. Minneapolis upzoned its single-family zones to multi-family use in 2018. Oregon followed with a law allowing duplexes in most single-family zones.
Still others, like the uber-progressive Berkeley, where many residents continue to fight upzoning, need an extra nudge. Since the administration’s proposal is voluntary, communities that continue to prize exclusive single-family housing over the economic benefits of reform can be expected to forego the carrots.
To some, relaxed zoning spells the end of “the suburbs.” The truth is far from it. The nationwide easing of zoning rules that artificially restrict certain types of housing arrangements would make the market more efficient, sometimes changing where “the suburbs” are, but not the opportunity to live there.
Those who want the urban-suburban synthesis of multi-family housing interspersed with light commerce will no longer be shut out of huge swaths of the country. Families who do not can more efficiently concentrate in single-family neighborhoods, and eased zoning everywhere likely would reduce their costs of keeping multi-family uses out.
Gentle relaxation of exclusionary zoning rules will not erase the suburbs. It will simply mark the next stage in an inevitable evolution already in progress. As the country’s population grows and moves, and cultural tastes change, so too do its neighborhoods.
Biden’s proposal is a small step. Unlike the many bad ideas in his infrastructure bill, it points in the right direction. Perhaps its success stories will spur recalcitrant zoning boards to end their exclusionary rules before federal authorities use them as pretexts to intervene in local rules that do not impede the free market.