The most shocking thing about banking crises is that few lessons are learned. In Indonesia, for example, legislation passed in 2004 established a Deposit Guarantee Institution (Lembaga Penjamin Simpanan) that commenced operations in 2005.
The new law inexplicably codifies virtually all the disastrous measures that were taken during the 1997–98 crisis.
Today, facing the threat of a new banking crisis, the Indonesian political class has done what the chattering classes have done worldwide: they have panicked. In consequence, bank deposits of up to about $210,000 are now guaranteed by the government, up from just $10,000 under the deposit guarantee law.
The Indonesian pattern is typical (See the accompanying table). After the 1997–98 crisis, deposit guarantee legislation was passed in order to prevent future crises. But, today, Indonesia faces a new potential crisis, and the authorities have responded by increasing the deposit guarantee.
Asia-Pacific governments most recent deposit guarantee policy changes
It is now twenty-one times the level provided by the original law and a potential crisis still lurks.
Is there a better way to organize banking, so that it would be safer, sounder and more stable? That is, so that it wouldn’t require backbreaking taxpayer bail outs?
Today, banks that accept deposits are not required to hold 100% liquid reserves against those deposits. Accordingly, banks operate under a fractional-reserve system that allows them to create liabilities: bank money.
To eliminate this element of discretion in the money circuit, fractional-reserve banking could be replaced by 100%-reserve banking. In short, banks would be required to cover all deposits they accept with 100% liquid reserves, which would restrict investments of depositors’ money into “safe” and liquid securities such as government bonds or bonds guaranteed by the government.
Under 100%-reserve banking, banks that accepted deposits would essentially be transformed into money-market mutual funds — “narrow banks” — which could not create credit.
Accordingly, depositors would no longer have to live in fear of being unable to withdraw their deposits because banks would have the liquid reserves to cover any withdrawals.
Banking panics, system-wide banking crises, and taxpayer bail outs would all be relegated to history.
Another important advantage of 100%-reserve banking is that banks would need very little equity capital to cover the small risks associated with the matching of their assets and deposit liabilities. This makes the 100%-reserve system particularly wellsuited for emerging economies, where banks are notoriously undercapitalized.
How would credit be supplied in such a money and banking system? Merchant (or investment) banks that do not accept deposits would assume that function. They would intermediate savings and generate credit (not money) by issuing shares and subordinated debt instruments (unsecured bonds that have lowranking claims on a company’s earnings and assets).
Safety, soundness, stability
This approach facilitates credit flows while separating money from credit. By doing so, it injects safety, soundness and stability into the credit circuit.
Indeed, shareholders would provide an important source of market discipline to the merchant banks because the banks’ owners would risk losing their investments in case of merchant bank failures.
The other element in the merchant banks’ capital structure would be provided by subordinated debt. This debt also provides an attractive source of market discipline because, as distinct from depositors, the holders of subordinated debt cannot withdraw their funds on demand when bad news surfaces.
The holders of subordinated debt would, therefore, have an incentive to monitor the merchant bankers carefully.
Would speculative entrepreneurial ventures never get loans because merchant banks would be too conservative? Not at all. Banks that specialized in riskier loans would simply issue subordinated debt at significantly higher interest rates. Investors would purchase these instruments, just as they purchase highyield junk bonds.
If banks that accept deposits were prohibited from creating bank money and were transformed into money-market mutual funds, bank runs would come to a halt. And more importantly, taxpayers would be off the hook, too.