The problem is that any reduction or even announcement of such a reduction in Fed assets could trigger a sharp fall in asset prices (especially in bond markets where duration risk is high) and shake market confidence—as seen in the 2013 Bernanke “taper tantrum” when he announced that the Fed would exit its large-scale asset purchase program. Financial markets have relied on the Fed “put” for a long time, and that expectation has made it difficult to change policy.
References
Barro, R. J., and Gordon, D. B. (1983) “A Positive Theory of Monetary Policy in a Natural Rate Model. Journal of Political Economy 91 (August): 589–610.
Beckworth, D. (2017) “The Knowledge Problem in Monetary Policy: The Case for Nominal GDP Targeting.” Mercatus on Policy Series (July 18). Mercatus Center, George Mason University.
Beckworth, D., and Hendrickson, J. R. (2016) “Nominal GDP Targeting and the Taylor Rule on an Even Playing Field.” Mercatus Working Paper, George Mason University (October).
Belongia, M. T., and Ireland, P. N. (2015) “A ‘Working’ Solution to the Question of Nominal GDP Targeting.” Macroeconomic Dynamics 19 (3): 508–35.
Bernanke, B. S. (2015) “Objections to Federal Reserve Accountability Bill.” Remarks presented at the conference on “The Fed in the 21st Century: Independence, Governance, and Accountability,” Brookings Institution, March 2. Available atwww.youtube.com/watch?v5KJmA5JDNpKg.
Bernholz, P. (2017) “The Implementation and Maintenance of a Monetary Constitution.” In J. A. Dorn (ed.) Monetary Alternatives: Rethinking Government Fiat Money, chap. 8. Washington: Cato Institute.
Board of Governors, Federal Reserve System (2017) Report on Monetary Policy (July 7). Available atwww.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/files/20170707_mprfullreport.pdf.
Boettke, P. J.; Salter, A. W.; and Smith, D. J. (2016) “Money as Meta-Rule: Buchanan’s Constitutional Economics as a Foundation for Monetary Stability.” George Mason University Working Paper in Economics, No. 16–49.
Borio, C. (2016) “Revisiting Three Intellectual Pillars of Monetary Policy.” Cato Journal 36 (2): 213–38.
Bradley, M. D., and Jansen, D. W. (1989) “Understanding Nominal GNP Targeting.” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review 71 (6): 31–40.
Brunner, K. (1980) “The Control of Monetary Aggregates.” In Controlling Monetary Aggregates III, 1–65. Boston: Federal Reserve Bank of Boston.
______ (1985) “Monetary Policy and Monetary Order.” In Monetary Policy and Monetary Regimes, 4–21. Center Symposia Series No. CS-17. Rochester, N.Y.: Center for Research in Government Policy and Business, Graduate School of Management, University of Rochester.
______ (1987) “Policy Coordination and the Dollar.” Shadow Open Market Committee: Policy Statement and Position Papers (PPS 87–01). Center for Research in Government Policy & Business, University of Rochester.
Buchanan, J. M. (1962) “Predictability: The Criterion of Monetary Constitutions.” In L. B. Yeager (ed.) In Search of a Monetary Constitution, 155–83. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.
______ (1988) “Comment by Dr. Buchanan.” In Prospects for a Monetary Constitution, 32–35; special issue of Economic Education Bulletin 28 (6).
______ (1989) “Reductionist Reflections on the Monetary Constitution.” Cato Journal 9 (2): 295–99.
Calomiris, C. W. (2017) “The Microeconomic Perils of Monetary Policy Experiments.” Cato Journal 37 (1): 1–15.
Christensen, L. (2011) “A Market Monetarist Version of the McCallum Rule.” The Market Monetarist:https://marketmonetarist.com/2011/10/09/a‑market-monetarist-version-of-the-mccallum-rule.
Dittman, R.; Gavin, W. T.; and Kydland, F. E. (1999) “Price-Level Uncertainty and Inflation Targeting.” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review (July/August): 23–33.
Dorn, J. A. (1987) “The Search for Stable Money: A Historical Perspective.” In J. A. Dorn and A. J. Schwartz (eds.) The Search for Stable Money: Essays on Monetary Reform, 1–28. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
______, ed. (2017) Monetary Alternatives: Rethinking Government Fiat Money. Washington: Cato Institute.
Dowd, K. (2017) “Monetary Freedom and Monetary Stability.” In J. A. Dorn (ed.) Monetary Alternatives: Rethinking Government Fiat Money, chap. 18. Washington: Cato Institute.
Dowd, K., and Hutchinson (2017) “From Excess Stimulus to Monetary Mayhem .” Cato Journal 37 (2): 303–28.
Fischer, S. (2017) “Committee Decisions and Monetary Policy Rules.” Speech presented at “The Structural Foundations of Monetary Policy,” a Hoover Institution Monetary Policy Conference, Stanford University (May 5).
Friedman, M. (1960) A Program for Monetary Stablity. New York: Fordham University Press.
______ (1962) Capitalism and Freedom. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
______ (1968) “The Role of Monetary Policy.” American Economic Review 58 (1): 1–17.
______ (1987) “Monetary Policy: Tactics versus Strategy.” In J. A. Dorn and A. J. Schwartz (eds.) The Search for Stable Money, 361–82. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Friedman, M., and Schwartz, A. J. (1963) A Monetary History of the United States, 1867–1960. Princeton, N. J.: Princeton University Press.
Gordon, R. J. (1985) “The Conduct of Domestic Monetary Policy.” In A. Ando et al. (eds.) Monetary Policy in Our Times. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.
Greenfield, R. L., and Yeager, L. B. (1983) “A Laissez-Faire Approach to Monetary Stability.” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 15 (August): 302–15.
Hall, R. (1981) “Lowering Inflation and Stimulating Economic Growth.” In Politics and the Oval Office: Toward Presidential Governance, 207–27. San Francisco: Institute for Contemporary Studies.
Haraf, W. S. (1986) “Monetary Velocity and Monetary Rules.” Cato Journal 6 (2): 641–62.
Hayek, F. A. (1945) “The Use of Knowledge in Society.” American Economic Review 35 (4): 519–30.
______ ([1974] 1989) “The Pretense of Knowledge: Nobel Memorial Lecture of December 4, 1974.” American Economic Review 79 (6): 3–7.
______ (1978) The Denationalisation of Money. 2nd ed. London: Institute of Economic Affairs.
Higgs, R. (1997) “Regime Uncertainty: Why the Great Depression Lasted So Long and Why Prosperity Resumed after the War.” The Independent Review 1 (4): 561–90.
Hubbard, G. (2017) “How to Keep the Fed from Following Its Models Off a Cliff.” Wall Street Journal (June 15).
Humphrey, T. M. (2014) “Averting Financial Crises: Advice from Classical Economists.” Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Focus 18 (4): 4–7.
Humphrey, T. M., and Timberlake, R. H. (2017) “The Real Bills Doctrine, the Gold Standard, and the Great Depression.” Unpublished manuscript.
Jordan, J. (2016) “Tools of Monetary Policy.” Sound Money Project (December 13):http://soundmoneyproject.org/2016/12/tools-of-monetary-policy. A project of the Atlas Network.
______ (2017) “Rethinking the Monetary Transmission Mechanism.” Cato Journal 37 (2): 361–84.
Kydland, F. E., and Prescott, E. C. (1977) “Rules Rather than Discretion: The Inconsistency of Optimal Plans.” Journal of Political Economy 85 (June): 473–91.
Madison, J. (1831) “[Letter] to Mr. Teachle” (Montpelier, March 15). In S. K. Padover (ed.), The Complete Madison: His Basic Writings, 292. New York: Harper and Bros. (1953).
McCallum, B. T. (1984) “Monetary Rules in the Light of Recent Experience.” American Economic Review 74 (May): 388–96.
______ (1989) Monetary Economics: Theory and Policy. New York: Macmillan.
______ (2004) “Misconceptions Regarding Rules vs. Discretion for Monetary Policy.” Cato Journal 23 (3): 365–72.
McCulloch, J. H. (1991) “An Error-Correction Mechanism for Long-Run Price Stability. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 23 (August, Part 2): 619–24.
Meltzer, A. H. (1983) “Monetary Reform in an Uncertain Environment.” Cato Journal 3 (1): 93–112. Reprinted in J. A. Dorn and A. J. Schwartz (eds.) The Search for Stable Money: Essays on Monetary Reform, 201–20. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1987.
______ (1989) “On Monetary Stability and Monetary Reform.” In J. A. Dorn and W. A. Niskanen (eds.) Dollars, Deficits, and Trade, 63–85. Boston: Kluwer. This paper was originally presented at the Third International Conference of the Institute for Monetary and Economic Studies at the Bank of Japan, June 3, 1987.
Niskanen, W. A. (1992) “Political Guidance on Monetary Policy.” Cato Journal 12 (1): 281–86.
O’Driscoll, G. P. Jr. (2016) “Monetary Policy and the Knowledge Problem.” Cato Journal 36 (2): 337–52.
Orphanides, A. (2017) “The Case Against the Case Against Monetary Rules.” Paper presented at the Shadow Open Market Committee meeting, Princeton Club, New York City (May 5).
Salter, A. W. (2017) “Some Political Economy of Monetary Rules.” The Independent Review 21 (3): 443–64.
Selgin, G. (1997) Less than Zero: The Case for a Falling Price Level in a Growing Economy. Hobart Paper No. 132. London: Institute of Economic Affairs.
______ (2016a) “Interest on Excess Reserves, Part 2.” Alt‑M (January 5):www.alt‑m.org/2016/01/05/interest-reserves-part-ii.
______ (2016b) “Real and Pseudo Monetary Rules.” Cato Journal 36 (2): 279–96.
______ (2017a) “On Shrinking the Fed’s Balance Sheet.” Alt‑M (February 23):www.alt‑m.org/2017/02/23/shrinking-the-feds-balance-sheet.
______ (2017b) “A Monetary Policy Primer, Part 10: Discretion or a Rule?” Alt‑M (May 11):www.alt‑m.org/2017/05/11/a‑monetary-policy-primer-part-10-discretion-or-a-rule.
______ (2017c) Money: Free and Unfree. Washington: Cato Institute.
______ (2017d) “Monetary Policy v. Fiscal Policy: Risks to Price Stability and the Economy.” Testimony before the U.S. House of Representatives Committee on Financial Services (July 21). Available atwww.cato.org/publications/testimony/monetary-policy-v-fiscal-policy-risks-price-stability-economy.
Selgin, G.; Beckworth, D.; and Bahadir, B. (2015) “The Productivity Gap: Monetary Policy, the Subprime Boom, and the Post-2001 Productivity Surge.” Journal of Policy Modeling 37 (2): 189–207.
Selgin, G.; Lastrapes, W. D.; and White, L. H. (2012) “Has the Fed Been a Failure?” Journal of Macroeconomics 34 (3): 569–96.
Selgin, G., and White, L. H. (1987) “The Evolution of a Free Banking System.” Economic Inquiry 25 (July): 439–57.
______ (1994) “How Would the Invisible Hand Handle Money?” Journal of Economic Literature 32 (December): 1718–49.
Sumner, S. B. (2014) “Nominal GDP Targeting: A Simple Rule to Improve Fed Performance.” Cato Journal 34 (2): 315–37.
Tatom, J. A. (2017) “How to Fix the Fed: The Ineffectiveness of the U.S. Central Bank’s Credit Policy.” The International Economy (Winter): 48–51.
Taylor, J. B. (1993) “Discretion versus Policy Rules in Practice.” Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 39: 195–214.
______ (2012) “Monetary Policy Rules Work and Discretion Doesn’t: A Tale of Two Eras.” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 44 (6): 1017–32.
______ (2015) “Getting Back to a Rules-Based Monetary Strategy.” Written version of keynote address given at the Shadow Open Market Committee’s Conference on “Getting Monetary Policy Back on Track,” Princeton Club, New York City, March 20.
______ (2017) “Rules versus Discretion: Assessing the Debate over the Conduct of Monetary Policy.” Paper presented at the Federal Reserve Bank of Boston Conference on “Are Rules Made to Be Broken? Discretion and Monetary Policy” (October 13).
Timberlake, R. T. (2013) Constitutional Money: A Review of the Supreme Court’s Monetary Decisions. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Vieira, E. Jr. (2017) “Gold and Silver as Constitutional Alternative Currencies.” In J. A. Dorn (ed.) Monetary Alternatives: Rethinking Government Fiat Money. Washington: Cato Institute.
Warburton, C. (1949) “Erratic Money: An Outline of the Theory of Monetary Disequilibrium.” Box 16, Warburton Collection, Special Collections, George Mason University Library, Fairfax, Va. (Unpublished book-length manuscript.)
______ (1966) Depression, Inflation, and Monetary Policy: Selected Papers, 1945– 1953. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins University Press.
White, L. H. (1989) Competition and Currency: Essays on Free Banking and Money. New York: New York University Press.
______ (1999) The Theory of Monetary Institutions. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.
______ (2012) “Making the Transition to a New Gold Standard.” Cato Journal 32 (2): 411–21.
______ (2017) “Experts and the Gold Standard.” Alt‑M (June 13). Available atwww.alt‑m.org/2017/06/13/experts-gold-standard.
White, L. H.; Vanberg, V. J.; and Köhler, E. A., eds. (2015) Renewing the Search for a Monetary Constitution. Washington: Cato Institute.
Woodford, M. (2003) Interest and Prices: Foundations of a Theory of Monetary Policy. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Yeager, L. B., ed. (1962) In Search of a Monetary Constitution. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.
______ (1986) “The Significance of Monetary Equilibrium.” Cato Journal 6 (2): 369–99.
______ (1992) “Toward Forecast-Free Monetary Institutions.” Cato Journal 12 (1) 53–73.
______ (1997) The Fluttering Veil: Essays on Monetary Disequilibrium. Edited by G. Selgin. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.
Yeager, L. B., and Greenfield, R. L. (1989) “Can Monetary Disequilibrium Be Eliminated?” Cato Journal 9 (2): 405–21.
1Orphanides (2017: 1) holds that “the presence of uncertainty … cannot serve as a valid argument for defending discretionary policy. Indeed, uncertainty raises the potential costs of discretion as it makes it harder to understand how large a policy deviation may be from what would have been the desirable systematic response to a shock.”
2See Financial CHOICE Act of 2017 (H.R. 10):https://financialservices.house.gov/uploadedfiles/hr_10_the_financial_choice_act.pdf.
3The analysis of alternative monetary rules in this article focuses on rules that are potentially stabilizing and omits rules such as the real bills doctrine that could be destabilizing. For an in-depth discussion of the real bills doctrine, see Humphrey and Timberlake (2017).
4For a summary of the debate, see Taylor (2015: 11).
5A useful overview of the case for rules over discretion is provided in Salter (2017: 444–48). See also (Taylor 2017).
6For a critique of Fischer’s “rule-by-experts” approach to monetary policymaking, see White (2017).
7See White (1999: chap. 10) for an overview of the time-inconsistency case for rules, as first presented by Kydland and Prescott (1977) and elaborated on by Barro and Gordon (1983).
8For a detailed discussion of the theory of monetary disequilibrium, see Warburton (1966, especially his list of postulates underlying that theory, pp. 28–29). Also see Yeager (1986,1997) and Dorn (1987).
9For an in-depth discussion of alternative monetary rules, see White (1999), Dorn (2017), and Salter (2017).
10For a discussion of meta-monetary rules, see Boettke, Salter, and Smith (2016). On the idea of a “monetary constitution,” see Yeager (1962) and White, Vanberg, and Köhler (2015).
11See Pub. L. 95–188, 91 Stat. 1387, enacted November 16, 1977.
12For these and other reasons, Beckworth and Hendrickson (2016) argue that the basic Taylor rule is inferior to a nominal GDP rule. Also see Selgin, Beckworth, and Bahadir (2015) on the case for a nominal GDP rule.
13One could argue that Friedman’s k percent rule was never really tried and that if it had been, monetary velocity may have been more stable (seeWhite 1999: 223).
14Haraf (1986: 361) has argued that, under a properly specified price-level rule, there would be increased certainty about future price levels that would improve the environment for nominal contracting. That improvement would reduce the lag between changes in the monetary base and the speed at which the observed price level approaches the target level. If so, a major objection to price-level targeting is removed. For further support of a price-level rule, see McCulloch (1991) and Dittman, Gavin, and Kydland (1999).
15Early proponents of nominal income targeting include Robert Hall (1981) and Robert Gordon (1985). George Selgin’s “productivity norm” is also a type of demand rule, in which the price level would be allowed to vary inversely with real output while maintaining a stable path of aggregate spending (Selgin 1997).
16Interest rates are not a good indicator of the stance of monetary policy: if the Fed increases money growth, and money incomes and inflation expectations rise, nominal interest rates will follow. Changes in base money are a better indicator, but only if base velocity is stable so there is a predictable relationship between base money, monetary aggregates, and nominal income. The best indicator is the behavior of spending itself.
17See White (1999: 223–24) for the simple analytics of the McCallum rule. Christensen (2011) provides “a market monetarist version of the McCallum rule.”
18On the importance of rules for obtaining monetary order and reducing the uncertainty present in a discretionary government fiat system, see Brunner (1985).
19Meltzer’s rule to stabilize the anticipated domestic price level of those countries who adopt his rule would still allow nominal exchange rates to vary with real exchange rates. In particular, “anticipated and actual exchange rates would be subject to change with changes in relative productivity growth, rates of growth of intermediation, differences in rates of saving, in expected returns to capital, in labor-leisure choice or other real changes” (Meltzer 1989: 80–81).
20On the impact of unconventional monetary policy on bank lending, especially the effect of overly zealous maroprudential regulation, see Calomiris (2017).
21There is no doubt that payment of interest on excess reserves (beginning in October 2008) at a rate exceeding interest on highly liquid assets (such as short-term Treasuries), has sterilized much of the newly created base money from the Fed’s large-scale asset purchases. Humphrey (2014: 7) argues that paying IOER increases the “demand for idle reserves” and prevents them from being “lent out into active circulation in the form of bank deposit money.” He notes that the Fed’s attempt to expand the broad money supply to counter the financial crisis was hampered by paying IOER, which defeated the Fed’s lender-of-last-resort function. According to Humphrey (in personal correspondence with the author), instead of paying a positive interest rate on excess reserves, the Fed should have charged a negative (penalty rate) to spur bank lending and deposit creation.
22Belongia and Ireland (2015) have argued that the Fed could use Divisia monetary aggregates to make long-run targeting of NGDP feasible.
23For a more detailed discussion, see Greenfield and Yeager (1983), and Yeager and Greenfield (1989).
24Bradley and Jansen (1989: 40) contend that changes in the assumptions about the labor market can make a price-level rule theoretically superior to a demand rule. Also, they argue that “ignorance of the correct equations, parameter values and lag structure that characterize the U.S. economy reduces the appeal of nominal GNP targeting.”
25See, e.g., White (1989), Selgin (2017c), Selgin and White (1987,1994).
26Selgin (2016a) provides a similar analysis.
27On the unsustainability of unconventional monetary policies and the exit problem, see Dowd and Hutchinson (2017: 313–17).