GSCs can affect the transmission of monetary policy by increasing currency substitution and by reshaping patterns of business-cycle synchronization. Currency substitution reduces the monetary authorities’ control over domestic liquidity by limiting the component over which the authorities have direct influence and by reducing the stability of money demand (El-Erian 1988). Substitution into the GSC is no different from substitution into existing fiat currencies. However, the GSC could intensify currency substitution due to easier accessibility. In addition, it could facilitate economic activities and trade links organized around Big Techs, and it could help reshape patterns of business-cycle synchronization, which might reduce the ability of monetary policy to respond to shocks.
The global adoption of a GSC with an independent unit of account could subject countries to the monetary stance of a private firm. Although privately issued money has circulated in various forms in the past (Champ 2007; King 1983; White 1995), the reach of a globally adopted GSC would be unprecedented. Therefore, the impact of any potential misuse of the payment system and monetary stance for private ends could exceed that of any private money previously seen.
The issuer could adjust the volume of issuances or the level of interest rates or fees in order to maximize its own profit, instead of aiming for price and output stabilization in countries that use the GSC. The potential for conflicts of interest would be especially large if that company is also a major provider of credit, the demand for which could come to depend upon its own monetary stance.
If the GSC were to have a price-stabilization rule relative to a basket of goods sold on the Big Tech’s platform, it could challenge notions of optimal currency areas based on the synchronization of national business cycles. Platform-based economic activities and other parts of an economy could experience different trends. The sectors closely associated with the platforms could become a source of shocks to other parts of the economy. Moreover, if the GSC pays an adjustable rate of return, changes to that rate of return may not be aligned with what is required to stabilize other parts of the economy.
The monetary policy implications of multipolarity depend on whether the multipolarity is characterized by country currency blocs or by currency competition within each country. If multipolarity is delineated by blocs of countries, with each country adopting one CBDC or GSC, then the monetary policy implications for countries that use it would mirror those of single-currency adoption. Each GSC currency bloc would become more similar to a currency union than to a “dollarized” economy. Nevertheless, as in a currency union, monetary policy could only be tailored to the bloc as a whole; it might not be of much help to countries whose business cycles diverge from the average bloc member.
Multipolarity could imply that each country witnesses the domestic use of multiple currencies, perhaps because the functions of money are unbundled, with different currencies preferred for different functions. The domestic monetary implications of substitution into multiple currencies resemble those of substitution into a single currency, but effective competition among GSC issuers could help alleviate to some extent the conflict of interest problems noted above and could enhance monetary stability in the longer term (Hayek 1976).
Nevertheless, multiple currencies could complicate exchange rate anchoring, if the domestic currency is still in use. Many countries that have experienced currency substitution into a single foreign currency have geared their monetary policy toward limiting bilateral exchange rate movements to stabilize domestic balance sheets exposed to the foreign currency. But with multiple currencies, exchange rate fluctuations between the foreign currencies would complicate such stabilization efforts.
GSCs can reduce the ability of central banks to control domestic financial conditions and to provide emergency liquidity assistance during stressful times. Financial conditions measure the cost of funding and reflect the underlying price of risk in the economy. Changes in financial conditions could alter incentives for risk taking and could lead to vulnerabilities in the financial system, affecting both business activity and financial stability over time.
As the global financial system becomes more integrated, domestic financial conditions of individual countries have been increasingly driven by so-called global financial cycles (Miranda-Agrippino and Rey 2020). The widespread adoption of a GSC could reinforce this trend. Global financial cycles could be associated with perceived changes in the safety and soundness of the ecosystem of the GSC arrangement. They could also be driven by interest-rate changes initiated by the GSC issuer. As a result, local central banks may find it more difficult to constrain boom-and-bust dynamics.
The GSC could worsen vulnerabilities from currency mismatches among banks and retail borrowers, again due to easier accessibility. Without appropriate safeguards, GSCs could facilitate illicit flows and could make it harder for regulatory authorities to enforce exchange restrictions and capital flow management (CFM) measures. GSCs could also affect financial stability if the credibility of their peg to fiat currencies becomes doubtful.
Greater currency substitution induced by GSC adoption could also make it harder for central banks to manage “run risks” in stressful times. For many emerging markets and developing countries, a run on the banking system is often associated with a run on the currency or the country (Laeven and Valencia 2018). In such cases, depositors would be incentivized to move their wealth into foreign assets.
The degree of accessibility of foreign assets is an important factor that depositors consider when choosing whether to launch a run on the bank. Another important factor is the availability of “lender-of-last-resort” assistance from the central bank that issues the currency. If opening and transferring to a digital wallet is faster and more accessible than opening and transferring to an account in a bank abroad — and considering that emergency liquidity assistance from the GSC issuing platform may not be easily available — incentives for depositors to launch a run could increase.
Global adoption of the GSC can give rise to systemic risks due to interconnectedness. Pressures on any component of the GSC ecosystem could quickly be transmitted across borders. The failure of a service provider (e.g., resellers, wallet providers, managers, or custodian/trustees of reserve assets) in one jurisdiction may lead users in another jurisdiction to question the safety and reliability of the GSC. Ultimately, weaknesses in one jurisdiction could raise risks for the entire ecosystem. This could lead to a potential breakdown of the global payment system — a situation in which payments worldwide could be interrupted.
In the scenario of multipolarity, currency competition within a jurisdiction could make local financial conditions more volatile. Low switching costs between CBDCs and GSCs could make the participation in a currency bloc or digital currency area unstable. Although competition could foster discipline in risk management in order to maintain the attractiveness of privately issued money in the longer term (Hayek 1976), currency competition might deliver stability only under certain restrictive conditions (Fernández-Villaverde and Sanches 2019). Indeed, there is no consensus among economists as to whether historical episodes of currency competition are associated with an improvement or deterioration in financial stability (e.g., White 1995).
In addition, competition could create incentives for GSC service providers to take on higher risks to gain market share in the short term. For example, GSC service providers might seek to gain a dominant market position by providing services at a loss in the short run with a view to recouping such losses through higher margins in the long run (capturing monopoly rents), or gaining from a possible subsequent too-big-to-fail subsidy. Thus, aggressive business models could be a driver of additional risks to the ecosystem.
On the positive side, the multipolarity scenario could create more opportunities for international risk sharing (Farhi and Maggiori 2017). This would be the case if the CBDCs and GSCs are not correlated, either because the issuing countries have asynchronized business cycles, or because the units of account of the GSCs are different from the fiat currencies.
GSC adoption could also help reduce transaction costs and frictions in international capital markets. From a lender’s or an investor’s perspective, GSCs, if bundled with big data derived from the e‑commerce and social networking platforms, might offer improved cross-border credit analytics and help lower information asymmetries. From a borrower’s perspective, a reduction in search and transaction costs could help improve access to foreign capital markets and lead to higher financial inclusion of less developed countries or of small firms across the world.
Furthermore, new classes of safe assets with superior features, such as triple-A-rated bonds denominated in the GSC units of account but embedded with smart contracts that offer attractive risk hedging properties, might emerge. They could offer the opportunity of portfolio diversification and the construction of better hedges against idiosyncratic external risk that countries might confront. For example, households and small firms in commodity exporting countries could have easier access to financial instruments that might help them hedge against volatilities in the prices of the commodity they produce and export.