In addition to the potential for abusive actions, there is also reason to be concerned about FSOC inaction. Strangely, FSOC and OFR have been largely silent about the mounting systemic risks in U.S. real estate, which many observers believe may be substantially overpriced. Indeed, it is not an exaggeration to say that FSOC seems to be uninterested in the only obvious and legitimate systemic risk facing the U.S. economy today.
The unprecedented pandemic of financial system collapses over the last four decades around the world is largely a story of real estate booms and busts (Jordà at al. 2015; Calomiris 2018). Real estate is central to systemic risk in many countries because of four facts. First, exposures to real estate risk inherently are highly correlated with each other and with the business cycle, which means that downturns in real estate markets can have large and sudden implications for massive amounts of loans and securities backed by real estate.
Second, real estate assets are unique and generally cannot be liquidated quickly at their full long-term value, which can imply large losses to holders who are forced to sell real estate quickly. Those losses can further exacerbate financial losses and magnify systemic risk.
Third, over the past 40 years worldwide, and especially in the United States, real estate is increasingly funded by government-protected and government-regulated entities. That protection encourages the politicization of real estate funding (given the strong short-term political incentives to subsidize mortgage risk).
Fourth, throughout the world, a large amount of commercial and/or residential real estate investment is being funded increasingly within banks, which rely primarily on short-term debt for their funding. As we witnessed during the Subprime Crisis in the United States, real estate losses produced substantial liquidity risk (beginning in August 2007 in the asset-backed commercial paper market, and continuing through September 2008 in the repo and interbank deposits markets), which deepened the losses during the crisis and magnified the general contraction in credit that ensued. But this is not just a problem of large banks. The loan portfolios of small banks in the United States are also highly exposed to residential and commercial real estate risk, which over the past two decades averaged about three-quarters of total lending by small banks.
Many observers see large banks as the only source of systemic risk in the economy, but that mistaken view forgets that the United States has been the most financially unstable developed economy in the world for more than a century, despite the fact that large banks are a recent development in the United States (Calomiris and Haber 2014: chaps. 6–7). The 1980s banking crises were all about real estate losses incurred by small banks — not just in housing, but also in commercial real estate, especially in the southwest and the northeast, and in agricultural real estate throughout the country.
It is not hard to see why FSOC has been silent about the excessive exposure to real estate in the banking system, the increased risk taking by the GSEs and the FHA, the failure to reform the GSEs, and the increasing riskiness of mortgages over the past three years. Any discussion about these important systemic risks would be politically inconvenient.
For example, no one expected Jacob Lew, the Treasury secretary in the same administration that appointed Mel Watt to head the Federal Housing Finance Agency (FHFA), to criticize Mr. Watt’s decisions to increase mortgage risk after his appointment as head of FHFA. Immediately upon assuming authority, Mr. Watt reduced the down payment limit on GSE-eligible mortgages from 5 percent to 3 percent. The GSEs remain in conservatorship, and the combination of the watering down of the “Qualified Mortgage” (QM) and “Qualified Residential Mortgage” (QRM) rules and exemptions (Gordon and Rosenthal 2016), alongside these lax FHFA standards, and the government’s funding of the GSEs and the FHA and VA, continue to ensure that government subsidization of housing finance risk — the central problem highlighted by the 2007-08 crisis — will continue.
The continuation of the government’s push for risky housing finance has resulted in a continuing escalation of mortgage risk.5 For first-time buyers, combined loan-to-value ratios have risen from 90.7 percent in February 2013 to 91.9 percent in January 2017, and the average debt service-to-income ratios rose over that period from an average of 36.4 percent to 37.7 percent. As of the end of January 2017, 28 percent of first-time buyers had debt service-to-income ratios in excess of the QM limit of 43 percent, which is four percentage points higher than it was two years earlier. Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac, FHA, and VA hold riskier mortgage portfolios than banks, and they account for about 96 percent of purchased mortgage volume.
Given the political push for providing financing subsidies in the form of government-sponsored encouragement of systemic mortgage risk, the FSOC prefers to focus its attention on “interconnectedness” when discussing systemic risk, rather than recognize the central importance of real estate finance in producing systemic shocks (Scott 2016, Calomiris 2018).
Nor does the FSOC care to focus on the potential for small banks’ funding of commercial and residential real estate to create systemic risk. Small banks are politically popular in Congress (which rightly worries that regulatory burdens are putting many of them out of business). Builders and realtors also are popular with both political parties (Calomiris and Haber 2014: chaps. 7–8; Gordon and Rosenthal 2016) and no one is going to point toward small banks’ outsized exposures to real estate, or any other exposures to real estate, as a problem. When I did so in congressional testimony (Calomiris 2015), I was attacked from both sides of the aisle for failing to appreciate the importance of the “American dream.” Of course, mortgage subsidies have little effect on housing affordability (currently at a long-term low in the United States) because they not only expand credit but also prop up home prices, but honesty about housing markets has always been in short supply in Washington.
When I talk to OFR economists about the need to focus attention on real estate risks, it often seems that people start looking at their shoes. I have found the economists at the OFR to be skilled and diligent, and I find much of the OFR’s research output quite useful, but they have a blindspot when it comes to the risk-creating policies of the Administration.
Stress Tests
As part of the resolution of the financial crisis, U.S. banks were stress tested by the Federal Reserve in 2009 (the Supervisory Capital Assessment Program). Beginning in 2011, stress tests became a regular feature of the regulatory apparatus and, beginning in 2014, stress tests were required as part of Dodd-Frank for all banks with more than $10 billion in assets.
In concert with reformed capital ratios, stress tests could be an effective means of encouraging bankers to think ahead — leading them to consider risks that could cause sudden losses of value, and prodding them to increase capital buffers and improve their risk management practices. As they are currently structured, however, stress tests violate basic principles of the rule of law that all regulations should adhere to. Banks that fail stress tests are punished for falling short of standards that are never stated (either in advance or after the fact). This makes stress tests a source of uncertainty rather than a helpful guide against unanticipated risks.
Fed officials have justified the lack of transparency and accountability in stress testing because of the need to ensure that banks do not game the test, but that is not a reasonable argument. Changing economic circumstances imply that every year the scenarios that are relevant for stress testing should change, and therefore scenario modeling should not be highly predictable on the basis of past years’ tests. Ex post disclosure of the tests, combined with learning over time, changes in scenarios that track changing market circumstances, the use of multiple scenarios designed by multiple teams of experts, and rotation of the people designing scenarios should provide more than adequate unpredictability about the specifics of any test to prevent gaming of the test by bankers. Keeping the details of the methodology of stress testing a permanent secret has very undesirable features: it makes it impossible for market participants to learn what regulators regard as appropriate modeling techniques and assumptions, thereby insulating the regulators from any accountability for poor test design.
Regulators not only impose unstated quantitative standards for meeting stressed scenarios, but they also retain the option of simply deciding that banks fail on the basis of a qualitative judgment unrelated even to their own secret model’s criteria. It is hard to believe that the current structure of stress tests could occur in a country like the United States, which prizes the rule of law, the protection of property rights, and adherence to due process.
Process Reform
How can we reform financial regulatory process to restore adherence to the rule of law? Some solutions are simple and obvious: Operation Choke Point is a sad episode in our nation’s history and its revival should be prevented by legislation. But, as the above examples show, there is a more general problem illustrated by Operation Choke Point, one that arises because of the increasing reliance on guidance, which allows regulators to avoid accountability for their actions.
I favor requiring regulators to rely on formal rule making rather than guidance, so that regulation can be based on clearly defined standards, debated in public, and enforced transparently. Over a short period of time, I propose that existing guidance should be phased out entirely and replaced by formal rules. This will be a massive undertaking, and I do not recommend it lightly. But it is crucial for restoring the rule of law to our financial system. Eliminating the reliance on guidance also will reduce regulatory risk substantially, with favorable consequences for both growth and stability.
In addition to this overarching reform, below I propose specific reforms that address the specific problems outlined above in the FSOC, the CFPB, and stress testing.
FSOC Reform
FSOC should be made as politically independent as possible, especially because it (and the OFR that advises it) should retain necessary access to privileged data. FSOC’s mission should be identifying problems related to systemic risk, especially potential shortcomings in the enforcement of regulatory standards.
Barth, Caprio and Levine’s (2012) proposal for a “Sentinel” is a potential model. In their formulation, this body would be administered independently but have access to privileged data, including information about the actions of regulators and supervisors. To accomplish that mission, the FSOC would have to be removed from the Treasury and established on other, independent footings. It may still make sense to have the FSOC meet with regulators (such as Fed governors, SEC commissioners, and FDIC officials) but to be able to oversee the actions of those parties effectively it must be separate from them.
The designation of SIFI status, like other regulatory designations, should follow from clear rules, not opaque discretionary judgments that invite the abuse of power. For example, in addition to size thresholds (which measure an institution’s systemic importance), the degree of a nonbank institution’s reliance on short-term debt, and the degree to which it uses short-term debt to fund illiquid investments, such as commercial real estate loans, could be taken into account explicitly (and quantitatively) when formulating a rule for what constitutes systemic importance.
CFPB Reform
The CFPB could play a constructive role in monitoring compliance with consumer protection laws, such as disclosure requirements, mortgage brokerage standards, fair lending requirements, and anti-discrimination statutes. It should focus on monitoring and enforcing compliance of the laws that exist (e.g., by using testers to root out discriminatory treatment of consumers), advise Congress on the creation of new laws, and engage in formal rule making that is consistent with specific powers delegated to it by Congress. These functions are analogous in the banking sphere to some of the activities of the SEC, and it seems natural for the CFPB to adopt a similar bipartisan commission structure, which will help to insulate it from counterproductive political pressures. In keeping with this new structure, the CFPB’s activities should no longer be funded by special access to Federal Reserve surplus.
Reforming Fed Stress Tests
Two important sets of reforms are needed to address the current deficiencies in the process governing stress tests. First, the criteria for stress tests must be clarified, and the stress tester (the Fed) must be made accountable for its approach to measuring compliance. The Fed does not need to predisclose the specific models it will use, but it does need to explain, and demonstrate that it is adhering to, a reasonable and transparent process to build the models that will be used to measure compliance. And it must disclose the models it employs with a lag, to ensure accountability for the quality of its testing standards.
One practice that would improve accountability and reduce the ability of banks to game the test would be for the Fed to invite independent teams to assist it in building models (perhaps using multiple models rather than one). The Fed could rotate its model-building personnel and alter its scenarios in light of changing economic circumstances, which would ensure that its models conform to best practice while also remaining somewhat unpredictable. Each year, the Fed could disclose the models that were used previously, which would ensure accountability by permitting detailed criticisms by academic and industry observers.
Improved regulatory accountability likely would produce improvements in stress testing. Currently, there is great room for improvement. Stress tests should focus realistically on the true loss of economic value under various forward looking scenarios, based on defensible cash flow forecasts, not just tangible asset loss projections or forecasts of broad financial accounting measures. To accomplish that objective, bank cash flows must be analyzed properly. Managerial accounts of revenues and expenses should be separated by line of business, and cash flow projections for each line of business under each scenario should be justified by reference to observable historical patterns. For example, under a scenario of severe housing finance decline, mortgage servicing income is likely to be more affected than asset management fees. To be able to realistically capture the effects of macroeconomic scenarios on bank condition the data used in stress testing must be improved dramatically.
Conclusion
Some readers will regard the proposed reforms presented here as quixotic. I recognize that politics, not just principled thinking, will guide regulatory reform. Nevertheless, in spite of the partisan acrimony that rages in Washington, there may be cause for some optimism when it comes to process reform. President Trump has called for an overhaul of financial regulation, and congressional Republicans have enunciated principles of reform that echo many of the process concerns discussed above. Furthermore, there is evidence that Democrats are also becoming increasingly concerned about principles of due process now that they no longer control the administration of regulation. Despite the partisan battles that have defined financial regulation throughout its history, it seems that now might be an ideal time for both parties to find common ground supporting a policy platform that depoliticizes financial regulation and strengthens the rule of law.
References
Barth, J. R.; Caprio Jr., G.; and Levine, R. (2012) Guardians of Finance: Making Regulations Work for Us. Cambridge, Mass: MIT Press.
Baude, W. (2016) “Congressional Control over Agencies: The Problem of Coercive Guidance.” Paper presented at the Hoover Institution Program on Regulation and the Rule of Law Conference. Available at www.hoover.org/sites/default/files/baude2c_congress_and_guidance_2b.pdf.
Boyd, S. E. (2017) Letter to Senators Thom Tillis and Mike Crapo (August 16).
Calomiris, C. W. (2015) “What’s Wrong with Prudential Regulation and How to Fix It.” Testimony before the U.S. House Committee on Financial Services (July 23).
__________ (2017a) “Reforming Financial Regulation.” Unpublished manuscript.
__________ (2017b) “Expert Report of Charles Calomiris.” Community Financial Services Association of America LTD, et al., Plaintiffs, v. Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, et al., Defendants, U.S. District Court for the District of Columbia, Civil Action No. 14–953-GK (January 11).
__________ (2018) “Taming the Two 800 Pound Gorillas in the Room.” In D. Evanoff, A. Malliaris, and G. Kaufman (eds.) Public Policy and Financial Economics: Essays in Honor of Professor George G. Kaufman, chap. 6. Hackensack, N. J.: World Scientific.
Calomiris, C. W., and Haber, S. H. (2014) Fragile By Design: The Political Origins of Banking Crises and Scarce Credit. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Consumer Financial Protection Bureau (2014) “Using Publicly Available Information to Proxy for Unidentified Race and Ethnicity” (Summer). Available at www.consumerfinance.gov/data-research/research-reports/using-publicly-available-information-to-proxy-for-race-and-ethnicity.
DeMuth, C. (2014) “Can the Administrative State Be Tamed?” Paper presented at the Hoover Institution Program on Regulation and the Rule of Law (December).
Epstein, R. A. (2014) “The Role of Guidances in Modern Administrative Procedures.” Paper presented at the Hoover Institution Program on Regulation and the Rule of Law (December).
Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, Office of the Inspector General (2015) The FDIC’s Role in Operation Choke Point and Supervisory Approach to Institutions that Conducted Business with Merchants Associated with High-Risk Activities, Report No. AUD-15–008 (September).
Goldman Sachs Global Markets Institute (2015) The Two-Speed Economy. Available at www.goldmansachs.com/our-thinking/public-policy/regulatory-feform/2‑speed-economy-report.pdf.
Gordon, S., and Rosenthal, H. (2016) “Political Actions by Private Interests: Mortgage Market Regulation in the Wake of Dodd-Frank.” Working Paper, New York University (May).
Hamburger P. (2014) Is Administrative Law Unlawful? Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Jordà, Ò.; Schularick, M.; and Taylor, A. M. (2015) “The Great Mortgaging: Housing Finance, Crises, and Business Cycles.” NBER Working Paper No. 20501.
Lux, M., and Greene, R. (2015) “The State and Fate of Community Banking.” Harvard Kennedy School of Government (February). Available at www.hks.harvard.edu/centers/mrcbg/publications/awp/awp37.
Pinto, E., and Peter, T. (2017) “National Mortgage Risk Index (NMRI) and Other Risk Measures.” AEI International Center on Housing Risk (January 30).
Piwowar, M. S. ( 2014) “Remarks at AEI Conference on Financial Stability” (July 15). Available at www.sec.gov/News/Speech/Detail/Speech/1370542309109.
Scott, H. S. (2016) Connectedness and Contagion: Protecting the Financial System from Panics. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.
U.S. Circuit Court for the District of Columbia (2016) PHH Corporation et al. v. Consumer Financial Protection Bureau. No. 15–1177 (October 11).
U.S. House of Representatives Committee on Financial Services (2015) “Unsafe at Any Bureaucracy: CFPB Junk Science and Indirect Auto Lending” (November 24). Available at http://financialservices.house.gov/uploadedfiles/11–24-15_cfpb_indirect_auto_staff_report.pdf.
U.S. House of Representatives Committee on Oversight and Government Reform (2014) “FDIC Involvement in ‘Operation Choke Point’” (December 8).
1See Calomiris (2017a) for a detailed review of each of these issues and proposals for regulatory standards that would be more likely to succeed.
2There are many definitions of “rule of law.” I use the term to refer to the predictable and nondiscriminatory enforcement of laws and regulations.
3See “Dodd-Frank Five Years Later: Barney Frank’s Greatest Victory, Regret,” November 6, 2015, available at http://mitsloan.mit.edu/newsroom/articles/dodd-frank-five-years-later-barney-franks-greatest-victory-regret.
4Opinion of Rosemary M. Collyer, U.S. District Judge, United States District Court for the District of Columbia, Metlife v. FSOC, March 30, 2016, available at www.metlife.com/assets/cao/sifiupdate/MetLife_v_FSOC — Unsealed_Opinion.pdf.
5The facts noted in this paragraph are taken from Pinto and Peter’s (2017) Power Point presentation.