Congress should

  • restore Social Security to long‐​term sustainable solvency; and

  • allow younger workers to privately invest a portion of their Social Security payroll taxes through individual accounts.

The United States is drowning in a sea of red ink. America’s national debt now exceeds $30 trillion and is growing. The economic consequences of this bipartisan profligacy are becoming increasingly apparent. But as massive as today’s debt is, it represents just the tip of the iceberg. Soon, entitlement programs, notably Social Security and Medicare, will begin to add trillions to the debt.

Social Security’s long-term unfunded liabilities now total $42.2 trillion. Congress’s failure to act is threatening America’s economic stability and promises to bury our children and grandchildren under a mountain of debt. Reform is not an option; it is a necessity. And Congress should act now.

But not all Social Security reforms are equal. Raising taxes and cutting benefits would have their own economic costs and would make a bad deal even worse for today’s younger workers. However, by allowing younger workers to privately invest their Social Security taxes through individual accounts, the United States could

  • help restore Social Security to long-term solvency, without massive tax increases;
  • provide workers with higher benefits than Social Security would otherwise be able to pay;
  • create a system that treats women, minorities, and young people more fairly;
  • increase national savings and economic growth;
  • allow low-income workers to accumulate real, inheritable wealth for the first time in their lives; and
  • give workers ownership and control over their retirement funds.

The Looming Crisis

Social Security is a “pay-as-you-go” program, in which Social Security taxes are used to immediately pay benefits for current retirees. It is not a “funded plan,” in which contributions are collected and invested in financial assets and then liquidated and converted into a pension at retirement. Rather, it is a simple wealth transfer from current workers to current retirees.

Table 1 shows a basic model of overlapping generations: people are born in every time period, live for two periods (the first as workers, the second as retirees), and finally die. As time passes, older generations are replaced by younger generations. The columns represent successive time periods, and the rows represent successive generations. Each generation is labeled by the period of its birth, so that Generation 1 is born in Period 1, and so on. In each period, two generations overlap, with younger workers coexisting with older retirees.

In Table 1, a pay-as-you-go pension system provides a startup bonus to Generation 0 retirees by taking contributions from Generation 1 workers to pay benefits to those already retired. Thus, Generation 0 retirees receive a windfall because they never paid taxes into the system. Subsequent generations both pay taxes and receive benefits. There is no direct relationship between taxes paid and benefits received.

As long as the wage base supporting Social Security grows faster than the number of recipients, the program can continue to pay higher benefits to those recipients. But the growth in the labor force has slowed dramatically. In 1950, for example, there were 16.5 covered workers for every retiree receiving benefits from the program. Since then, Americans have been living longer and having fewer babies. As a result, there are now just 2.7 covered workers per beneficiary; and by 2040, there will be only 2.2 (Figure 1). Real wage growth (especially in wages below the payroll tax cap) has not been nearly fast enough to offset this demographic shift.

As Figure 2 shows, Social Security is already running a cash-flow deficit. In 2020, for instance, the program had paid out roughly $65 billion more in benefits than it took in through taxes. That might seem a small amount of money in a world of trillion-dollar deficits, but without reform, this shortfall will continue to grow. Very soon, Social Security’s deficit will reach levels that threaten to explode our overall budget deficit. Along with Medicare and Medicaid, Social Security will be one of the major drivers of our country’s long-term debt.

In theory, of course, Social Security is supposed to continue paying benefits by drawing on the Social Security Trust Fund until 2034, after which the Trust Fund will be exhausted. At that point, by law, Social Security benefits will have to be cut by approximately 22 percent.

In reality, the Social Security Trust Fund is not an asset that can be used to pay benefits. Perhaps the best description of the Trust Fund can be found in the Clinton administration’s fiscal year 2000 budget:

These [Trust Fund] balances are available to finance future benefit payments and other Trust Fund expenditures—but only in a bookkeeping sense.… They do not consist of real economic assets that can be drawn down in the future to fund benefits. Instead, they are claims on the Treasury that, when redeemed, will have to be financed by raising taxes, borrowing from the public, or reducing benefits or other expenditures. The existence of large Trust Fund balances, therefore, does not, by itself, have any impact on the Government’s ability to pay benefits.

Even if Congress can find a way to redeem the bonds, the Trust Fund surplus will be completely exhausted by 2034. At that point, Social Security will have to rely solely on revenue from the payroll tax—but that revenue will not be sufficient to pay all promised benefits. Overall, Social Security faces unfunded liabilities of $42.2 trillion over the infinite horizon. Clearly, Social Security is not sustainable in its current form. That means that Congress will again be forced to resort to raising taxes and/​or cutting benefits to enable the program to stumble along.

Other Issues with Social Security

Social Security taxes are already so high, relative to benefits, that Social Security has quite simply become a bad deal for younger workers, providing a poor, below-market rate of return. This poor rate of return means that many young workers’ retirement benefits will be far lower than if they were able to invest those funds privately.

In addition, Social Security taxes displace private saving options, resulting in a large net loss of national savings, reducing capital investment, wages, national income, and economic growth. Moreover, by increasing the cost of hiring workers, the payroll tax substantially reduces wages, employment, and economic growth.

After all the economic analysis, however, perhaps the single most important reason for transforming Social Security into a system of individual accounts is that it would give American workers true ownership of and control over their retirement benefits.

Many Americans believe that Social Security is an “earned right.” That is, because they have paid Social Security taxes, they are entitled to receive Social Security benefits. The government encourages this belief by referring to Social Security taxes as “contributions,” as in the Federal Insurance Contributions Act (or FICA). However, in the 1960 case of Flemming v. Nestor, the U.S. Supreme Court ruled that workers have no legally binding contractual or property right to their Social Security benefits and that those benefits can be changed, cut, or even taken away at any time.

As the Court stated, “To engraft upon Social Security a concept of ‘accrued property rights’ would deprive it of the flexibility and boldness in adjustment to ever changing conditions which it demands.” That decision built on a previous case from 1937, Helvering v. Davis, in which the Court had ruled that Social Security is not a contributory insurance program, stating that “the proceeds of both the employer and employee taxes are to be paid into the Treasury like any other internal revenue generally, and are not earmarked in any way.”

In fact, the Social Security statement mailed to workers contains this caveat:

Your estimated benefits are based on current law. Congress has made changes to the law in the past and can do so at any time. The law governing benefit amounts may change because, by 2034, the payroll taxes collected will be enough to pay only about 78 percent of scheduled benefits.

In effect, Social Security turns older Americans into supplicants, dependent on the political process for their retirement benefits. If they work hard, play by the rules, and pay Social Security taxes their entire lives, they earn the privilege of going hat in hand to the government and hoping that politicians decide to give them some money for retirement.

Options for Reform

There are few options for dealing with the problem. This is not an opinion shared only by supporters of individual accounts. As former president Bill Clinton pointed out, the only ways to keep Social Security solvent are to

  1. raise taxes;
  2. cut benefits; or
  3. get a higher rate of return through private capital investment.

Certainly, throughout its history, Social Security taxes have been raised frequently to keep the system financially viable. The initial Social Security tax was 2 percent (split between the employer and employee), capped at $3,000 of earnings. That made for a maximum tax of $60. Since then, as Figure 3 shows, the payroll tax rate and the ceiling at which wages are subject to the tax have been raised a combined total of 67 times. Today, the tax is 12.4 percent, capped at $147,000, for a maximum tax of $18,228. Even adjusting for inflation, that represents more than a 1,456 percent increase.

Alternatively, Congress can reduce Social Security benefits. Restoring the program to solvency would require an immediate 21 percent cut to benefits. Suggested changes include raising the retirement age further, trimming cost-of-living adjustments, means testing, or changing the wage-price indexing formula.

Obviously, there are better and worse ways to make these changes. But, as described above, most younger workers will receive returns far below those provided by private investment. Some will actually receive less in benefits than they pay into the system—a negative return. Both tax hikes and benefit reductions further reduce the return that workers can expect on their contributions (taxes).

Perhaps the best way to reduce Social Security benefits would be to change the formula used to calculate the initial benefit so that benefits are indexed to price inflation rather than national wage growth. Since wages over the long run have tended to grow at a rate roughly 1 percentage point faster than prices, such a change would hold future Social Security benefits constant in real terms but would eliminate the benefit escalation that is built into the current formula. The Congressional Budget Office (CBO) estimates that this change would reduce scheduled outlays by 7 percent in 2040 and 40 percent by 2080. This reform would result in the largest reduction in the actuarial shortfall of any options that the CBO analyzed, representing an 80 percent improvement. Variations on this approach would apply the formula change only to higher-income seniors, preserving the current wage-indexed formula for low-income seniors.

Better Reform: Personal Accounts

Ultimately, benefit reductions or tax increases are the only ways to restore Social Security to permanent sustainable solvency. But Social Security taxes are already so high relative to benefits that Social Security has quite simply become a bad deal for younger workers, providing a low, below-market rate of return. It makes sense, therefore, to combine any reduction in government-provided benefits with an option for younger workers to save and invest a portion of their Social Security taxes through individual accounts.

Table 2 shows what that would mean. Unlike the current Social Security system, each working generation’s contributions would actually be saved and would accumulate as time passes. The accumulated funds, including the returns earned through real investment, would then be used to pay that generation’s benefits when they retire. Under a funded system, there would be no transfer from current workers to current retirees. Each generation pays for its own retirement.

In a funded system, there is a direct link between contributions and benefits. Each generation receives benefits equal to its contribution plus the returns the investments earn. And because real investment takes place and the rate of return on capital investment can be expected to exceed the growth in wages, workers can expect to receive higher returns than under the current system.

Moving to a system of individual accounts would allow workers to take advantage of the potentially higher returns available from capital investment. In a dynamically efficient economy, the return on capital will exceed the rate of return on labor and therefore will be higher than the benefits that Social Security can afford to pay. In the United States, the return on capital has generally run about 2.5 percentage points higher than the return on labor.

True, capital markets are both risky and volatile. But private capital investment remains remarkably safe over the long term. For example, a 2012 Cato Institute study looked at a worker retiring in 2011, near the nadir of the stock market’s recession-era decline. If that worker had been allowed to invest the employee half of the Social Security payroll tax over his working lifetime, he would have retired with more income than if he relied on Social Security. Indeed, even in the worst-case scenario—a low-wage worker who invested entirely in bonds—the benefits from private investment would equal those from traditional Social Security. Although there are limits and caveats to this type of analysis, it clearly shows that the argument that private investment is too risky compared with Social Security does not hold up.

Low-income workers would be among the biggest winners under a system of privately invested individual accounts. Private investment would pay low-income workers significantly higher benefits than can be paid by Social Security. And that does not take into account the fact that black people, other minorities, and people who are poor have below-average life expectancies. As a result, they tend to live fewer years in retirement and collect less in Social Security benefits than do white people. In a system of individual accounts, they would each retain control over the funds paid in and could pay themselves higher benefits over their fewer retirement years, or leave more to their children or other heirs.

The higher returns and benefits of a private, invested system would be most important to low-income families, as they most need the extra funds. The funds saved in the individual retirement accounts, which could be left to the children of the poor, would also greatly help families break out of the cycle of poverty. Similarly, the improved economic growth, higher wages, and increased jobs that would result from an investment-based Social Security system would be most important to people who are poor. Without reform, low-income workers will be hurt the most by the higher taxes or reduced benefits that will be necessary if we continue our current course.

In addition, with average- and low-wage workers accumulating large sums in their own investment accounts, the distribution of wealth throughout society would become far broader than it is today. No policy proposed in recent years would do more to expand capital ownership than allowing younger workers to invest a portion of their Social Security taxes through personal accounts. Even the lowest-paid American worker would benefit from capital investment.

It should be noted that individual accounts do not, by themselves, fix Social Security’s solvency. Rather they compensate younger workers for benefit cuts that will be necessary to restore the system to fiscal solvency. Indeed, there will be a period of transition that requires younger workers both to bear the cost of the new system of individual accounts and to support the existing system for current recipients. Still, on net, younger workers will be better off when compared with the level of benefits that the existing system can pay given current taxes.

Cato’s Social Security Plan

  • Individuals will be able to privately invest “the amount they contribute through their portion of the payroll taxes, 6.2 percent of wages” in individual accounts. Those who choose to do so will forfeit all future accrual of Social Security benefits.
  • Individuals who choose individual accounts will receive a recognition bond based on past contributions to Social Security. The zero coupon bonds will be offered to all workers who have contributed to Social Security, regardless of how long they have been in the system, but will be offered on a discounted basis.
  • Allowable investment options for the individual accounts will be based on a three‐​tiered system: a centralized, pooled collection and holding point; a limited series of investment options, with a life‐​cycle fund as a default mechanism; and a wider range of investment options for individuals who accumulate a minimum level in their accounts.
  • At retirement, individuals will be given the option of purchasing a family annuity or taking a programmed withdrawal. The two options will be mandated only to the level needed to provide an income above a certain minimum. Funds in excess of the amount required to achieve that minimum level of retirement income can be withdrawn in a lump sum.
  • Individuals who accumulate sufficient funds within their account to allow them to purchase an annuity that will keep them above a minimum income level in retirement will be able to opt out of the Social Security system in its entirety.
  • The remaining 6.2 percentage points of payroll taxes that are paid by the employer will be used to pay transition costs and to fund disability and survivor benefits. Once, far in the future, transition costs are fully paid for, this portion of the payroll tax will be reduced to the level necessary to pay survivor and disability benefits.
  • The Social Security system will be restored to a solvent pay-as-you-go program before individual accounts are developed and implemented. Workers who choose to remain in the traditional Social Security system will receive whatever level of benefits Social Security can pay with existing Trust Fund levels. The best method for restoring the system’s solvency is to change the initial benefit formula from wage indexing to price indexing.

Conclusion

Social Security is not sustainable without reform. Simply put, it cannot pay promised future benefits with current levels of taxation. Every year that we delay reforming the system increases the size of Social Security’s shortfall and makes the inevitable changes more painful.

Raising taxes or cutting benefits alone will only make a bad deal worse. At the same time, workers have no ownership of their benefits, and Social Security benefits are not inheritable. That reality is particularly problematic for low‐​wage workers and minorities. Perhaps most important, the current Social Security system gives workers no choice or control over their financial future.

It is long past time for Congress to act.

Suggested Readings

Edwards, Chris. “Federal Debt and Unfunded Entitlement Promises.” Cato at Liberty (blog), Cato Institute, January 21, 2022.

Miron, Jeffrey. Fiscal Imbalance: A Primer. Washington: Cato Institute, 2015.

Tanner, Michael. Going for Broke: Deficits, Debt, and the Entitlement Crisis. Washington: Cato Institute, 2015.

———. “The 6.2 Percent Solution: A Plan for Reforming Social Security.” Cato Institute Social Security Choice Paper no. 32, February 17, 2004.

———. “Still a Better Deal: Private Investment vs. Social Security.” Cato Institute Policy Analysis no. 692, February 13, 2012.