1. “Fact Sheet: Executive Order on Promoting Competition in the American Economy,” White House, updated July 9, 2021.
2. Peter Thiel, “Competition Is for Losers,” Wall Street Journal, September 12, 2014.
3. David Autor et al., “The Fall of the Labor Share and the Rise of Superstar Firms,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 135, no. 2 (May 2020): 645–709, https://doi.org/10.1093/qje/qjaa004; some examples are discussed in Ryan Bourne, “Is This Time Different? Schumpeter, the Tech Giants, and Monopoly Fatalism,” Cato Institute Policy Analysis no. 872, June 18, 2019.
4. Blake J. Harris, Console Wars: Sega, Nintendo, and the Battle That Defined a Generation (New York: Dey Street Books, June 2, 2015).
5. Richard B. Freeman et al., “Wal‐Mart Innovation and Productivity: A Viewpoint,” Canadian Journal of Economics 44, no. 2 (2011): 486–508.
6. Paul Ellickson, “The Evolution of the Supermarket Industry: From A&P to Walmart,” in Handbook on the Economics of Retailing and Distribution, ed. Emek Basker (Cheltenham, England: Edward Elgar Publishing, 2016), pp. 368–91.
7. Martin Campbell-Kelly and Daniel D. Garcia-Swartz, “The Mainframe Computer Industry,” in From Mainframes to Smartphones: A History of the International Computer Industry (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2015), pp. 11–27.
8. Martin Campbell-Kelly and Daniel D. Garcia-Swartz, “Microcomputers and Personal Computers in the American Market,” in From Mainframes to Smartphones, pp. 105–23.
9. Steven N. Kaplan, ed., Mergers and Productivity (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2000).
10. For evidence of the latter effect, see Allen N. Berger et al., “The Dynamics of Market Entry: The Effects of Mergers and Acquisitions on Entry in the Banking Industry,” Journal of Business 77, no. 4 (2004): 797–834.
11. The idea that the threat of competition can be sufficient to prompt firms to behave competitively was developed in William J. Baumol, John C. Panzar, and Robert D. Willig, Contestable Markets and the Theory of Industry Structure (New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, 1982).
12. Mihir N. Mehta, Suraj Srinivasan, and Wanli Zhao, “Political Influence and Merger Antitrust Reviews,” Working Paper 19–114, Harvard Business School, June 4, 2019.
13. An example is the Phoebus cartel, an agreement of lightbulb manufacturers in the first half of the 20th century to reduce the useful life of such bulbs; in the absence of proper externality pricing, output restrictions by cartels may have beneficial effects when they reduce production of goods with negative externalities. An example would be the Organization of the Petroleum Exporting Countries discouraging the use of fossil fuels.
14. Margaret C. Levenstein and Valerie Y. Suslow, “What Determines Cartel Success?,” Journal of Economic Literature 44, no. 1 (2006): 43–95.
15. Eric Goldschein, “The Incredible Story of How De Beers Created and Lost the Most Powerful Monopoly Ever,” Business Insider, December 19, 2011; and Tim Treadgold, “Diamond Wars; and the Winner Is Not Natural!,” Forbes, October 11, 2019.
16. Paul Zimnisky, “De Beers’ Market Share History,” Diamond Loupe, https://www.thediamondloupe.com/sites/awdcnewswall/files/attachments/De%20Beers%20Market%20Share%20History.pdf; and Edahn Golan, “De Beers’ Market Share Falls in 2019, Hides a Surprise,” Edahn Golan Diamond Research & Data, September 30, 2020.
17. Fiona S. Morton, “Entry and Predation: British Shipping Cartels 1879–1929,” Journal of Economics & Management Strategy 6, no. 4 (1997): 679–724.
18. John S. McGee, “Predatory Price Cutting: The Standard Oil (N. J.) Case,” Journal of Law and Economics 1 (1958): 137–69.
19. Robert W. Crandall and Clifford Winston, “Does Antitrust Policy Improve Consumer Welfare? Assessing the Evidence,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 17, no. 4 (2003): 3–26.
20. Bryan Caplan, “What Does Public Schooling Teach U.S. about Predatory Pricing?,” EconLog (blog), March 11, 2014.
21. Each state regulates harbor pilots differently, but the industry is usually heavily regulated by state boards not only through licenses but by restricting the number of pilots. For more details, see “Training & Qualifications,” Florida Harbor Pilots, https://floridapilots.com/about/training-qualifications/.
22. Petra Moser and Alessandra Voena, “Compulsory Licensing: Evidence from the Trading with the Enemy Act,” American Economic Review 102, no. 1 (February 2012): 396–427.
23. Esteban Rossi-Hansberg, Pierre-Daniel Sarte, and Nicholas Trachter, “Diverging Trends in National and Local Concentration,” NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2020 35 (May 2021): 115–50.
24. Chang-Tai Hsieh and Esteban Rossi-Hansberg, “The Industrial Revolution in Services,” NBER Working Paper no. 25968, June 2019.
25. Sharat Ganapati, “Growing Oligopolies, Prices, Output, and Productivity,” American Economic Journal: Microeconomics 13, no. 3 (August 2021): 309–27.
26. David Autor et al., “The Fall of the Labor Share and the Rise of Superstar Firms,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 135, no. 2 (May 2020): 645–709, https://doi.org/10.1093/qje/qjaa004.
27. Ryan Bourne, “Does Rising Industry Concentration Signify Monopoly Power?,” Cato Institute Economic Policy Brief no. 2, February 13, 2020.
28. Ganapati, “Growing Oligopolies.”
29. Jan De Loecker, Jan Eeckhout, and Gabriel Unger, “The Rise of Market Power and the Macroeconomic Implications,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 135, no. 2 (May 2020): 561–644.
30. “Profit Margins: The Death of a Chart,” Philosophical Economics (blog), March 30, 2014.
31. Jeffrey Miron and Pedro Braga Soares, “Do Antitrust Concerns Imply More or Less Privacy?,” Cato at Liberty (blog), Cato Institute, June 15, 2021.
32. Sara Morrison, “Google Is Done with Cookies, but That Doesn’t Mean It’s Done Tracking You,” Vox Recode, March 3, 2021.
33. Ingo Vogelsang, “Net Neutrality Regulation: Much Ado about Nothing?,” Review of Network Economics 17, no. 3 (2018): 225–43.
34. Anna-Maria Kovacs, “U.S. Broadband Networks Rise to the Challenge of Surging Traffic during the Pandemic,” Center for Business and Public Policy, McDonough School of Business, Georgetown University, June 2020, https://georgetown.app.box.com/s/8e76udzd1ic0pyg42fqsc96r1yzkz1jf; and George S. Ford, “COVID-19 and Broadband Speeds: A Multi-Country Analysis,” Phoenix Center Policy Bulletin no. 49, May 2020.
35. Roslyn Layton, “Net Neutrality and Mobile App Innovation in Denmark and Netherlands 2010–2016,” Review of Network Economics 17, no. 3 (2018): 207–24, https://doi.org/10.1515/rne-2019–0012.
36. Raffaele Conti, “Do Non-competition Agreements Lead Firms to Pursue Risky R&D Projects?,” Strategic Management Journal 35, no. 8 (August 2014): 1230–48, https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.2155.
37. A survey of labor force participants finds that those who signed noncompetes along with accepting a job offer received 9.7 percent higher wages and had an 11 percent higher likelihood of receiving training the year before the survey. See Evan Starr, James J. Prescott, and Norman Bishara, “Noncompete Agreements in the US Labor Force,” Journal of Law and Economics 64, no. 1 (February 2021): 53–84.
38. Evidence suggests airlines already use dynamic pricing to price discriminate business travelers for the benefit of leisure consumers. See Kevin R. Williams, “The Welfare Effects of Dynamic Pricing: Evidence from Airline Markets,” NBER Working Paper no. 28989, July 2021.
39. Similar measures apply to internet service provision contracts, namely the limitation of early termination fees and restriction of ISP-landlord contracts that limit tenant choices.
40. The proposed measures are “broadband nutrition facts” labels for internet plans, hospital price transparency rules to avoid surprise billing, standardized health care plan options to facilitate comparison shopping, fee disclosure requirements for airlines, and tighter standards for “Product of the United States” meat labels.
41. Gary D. Leff and Patrick McLaughlin, “Transparency of Airline Ancillary Fees and Other Consumer Protection Issues,” Mercatus Center, George Mason University, September 22, 2014.
42. Federally mandated occupational licensing deregulation could have the long-run negative impact of encouraging more federal regulation generally; on the effects of occupational licensing measures, see Morris M. Kleiner and Ming Xu, “Occupational Licensing and Labor Market Fluidity,” NBER Working Paper no. 27568, July 2020.
43. Petra Moser, “Patents and Innovation: Evidence from Economic History,” Stanford Law and Economics Olin Working Paper no. 437, December 2012, http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2180847.
44. See, for example, Natalie Chen, Jean Imbs, and Andrew Scott, “The Dynamics of Trade and Competition,” Journal of International Economics 77, no. 1 (2009): 50–62.
45. Mary Amiti, Stephen J. Redding, and David E. Weinstein, “The Impact of the 2018 Tariffs on Prices and Welfare,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 33, no. 4 (2019): 187–210.
46. Kishore Gawande and Bernard Hoekman, “Lobbying and Agricultural Trade Policy in the United States,” International Organization 60, no. 3 (2006): 527–61.
47. Colin Grabow, Inu Manak, and Daniel J. Ikenson, “The Jones Act: A Burden America Can No Longer Bear,” Cato Institute Policy Analysis no. 845, June 28, 2018; and Ryan A. Bourne, “The Consumer Costs of Anticompetitive Regulations,” Department of Justice, https://www.justice.gov/atr/page/file/1067236/download.
48. “USDA Subsidies in the United States Totaled $424.4 Billion from 1995–2020,” Environmental Working Group Farm Subsidy Database.